Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m., EDT
July 13, 2018
Monetary Policy rePort
July 13, 2018
Letter of transmittaL
B  G  
F R S
Washington, D.C., July 13, 2018
T P   S
T S   H  R
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report pursuant to
section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
Sincerely,
Jerome H. Powell, Chairman
Adopted effective January24, 2012; as amended effective January30, 2018
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is rmly committed to fullling its statutory
mandate from the Congress of promoting maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate
long-term interest rates. The Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions to the public
as clearly as possible. Such clarity facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and
businesses, reduces economic and nancial uncertainty, increases the eectiveness of monetary
policy, and enhances transparency and accountability, which are essential in a democratic society.
Ination, employment, and long-term interest rates uctuate over time in response to economic and
nancial disturbances. Moreover, monetary policy actions tend to inuence economic activity and
prices with a lag. Therefore, the Committee’s policy decisions reect its longer-run goals, its medium-
term outlook, and its assessments of the balance of risks, including risks to the nancial system that
could impede the attainment of the Committee’s goals.
The ination rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the
Committee has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for ination. The Committee rearms its
judgment that ination at the rate of 2percent, as measured by the annual change in the price
index for personal consumption expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the
Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate. The Committee would be concerned if ination were running
persistently above or below this objective. Communicating this symmetric ination goal clearly to the
public helps keep longer-term ination expectations rmly anchored, thereby fostering price stability
and moderate long-term interest rates and enhancing the Committee’s ability to promote maximum
employment in the face of signicant economic disturbances. The maximum level of employment
is largely determined by nonmonetary factors that aect the structure and dynamics of the labor
market. These factors may change over time and may not be directly measurable. Consequently,
it would not be appropriate to specify a xed goal for employment; rather, the Committee’s policy
decisions must be informed by assessments of the maximum level of employment, recognizing that
such assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision. The Committee considers a
wide range of indicators in making these assessments. Information about Committee participants’
estimates of the longer-run normal rates of output growth and unemployment is published four
times per year in the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections. For example, in the most
recent projections, the median of FOMC participants’ estimates of the longer-run normal rate of
unemployment was 4.6percent.
In setting monetary policy, the Committee seeks to mitigate deviations of ination from its
longer-run goal and deviations of employment from the Committee’s assessments of its maximum
level. These objectives are generally complementary. However, under circumstances in which the
Committee judges that the objectives are not complementary, it follows a balanced approach in
promoting them, taking into account the magnitude of the deviations and the potentially dierent
time horizons over which employment and ination are projected to return to levels judged
consistent with its mandate.
The Committee intends to rearm these principles and to make adjustments as appropriate at its
annual organizational meeting each January.
statement on Longer-run goaLs and monetary PoLicy strategy
contents
Note: This report reects information that was publicly available as of noon EDT on July12, 2018.
Unless otherwise stated, the time series in the gures extend through, for daily data, July11, 2018; for monthly data,
June2018; and, for quarterly data, 2018:Q1. In bar charts, except as noted, the change for a given period is measured to
its nal quarter from the nal quarter of the preceding period.
For gures 16 and 34, note that the S&P 500 Index and the Dow Jones Bank Index are products of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its afliates and
have been licensed for use by the Board. Copyright © 2018 S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a division of S&P Global, and/or its afliates. All rights reserved.
Redistribution, reproduction, and/or photocopying in whole or in part are prohibited without written permission of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC. For more
information on any of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC’s indices please visit www.spdji.com. S&P® is a registered trademark of Standard & Poor’s Financial
Services LLC, and Dow Jones® is a registered trademark of Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC. Neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark
Holdings LLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors make any representation or warranty, express or implied, as to the ability of any index to
accurately represent the asset class or market sector that it purports to represent, and neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings
LLC, their afliates nor their third party licensors shall have any liability for any errors, omissions, or interruptions of any index or the data included therein.
For gure A in the box “Interest on Reserves and Its Importance for Monetary Policy,” note that neither DTCC Solutions LLC nor any of its afliates shall
be responsible for any errors or omissions in any DTCC data included in this publication, regardless of the cause and, in no event, shall DTCC or any of
its afliates be liable for any direct, indirect, special or consequential damages, costs, expenses, legal fees, or losses (including lost income or lost prot,
trading losses and opportunity costs) in connection with this publication.
Summary ..................................................1
Economic and Financial Developments ......................................... 1
Monetary Policy
........................................................... 2
Special Topics
............................................................. 2
Part 1: Recent Economic and Financial Developments ................ 5
Domestic Developments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Financial Developments
.................................................... 23
International Developments
................................................. 30
Part 2: Monetary Policy ....................................... 35
Part 3: Summary of Economic Projections ......................... 47
The Outlook for Economic Activity ............................................ 48
The Outlook for Ination
................................................... 50
Appropriate Monetary Policy
................................................ 51
Uncertainty and Risks
...................................................... 51
Abbreviations ..............................................63
List of Boxes
The Labor Force Participation Rate for Prime-Age Individuals ......................... 8
The Recent Rise in Oil Prices
................................................ 16
Developments Related to Financial Stability
..................................... 26
Complexities of Monetary Policy Rules
......................................... 37
Interest on Reserves and Its Importance for Monetary Policy
......................... 44
Forecast Uncertainty
....................................................... 62
1
summary
Economic activity increased at a solid pace
over the rst half of 2018, and the labor
market has continued to strengthen. Ination
has moved up, and in May, the most recent
period for which data are available, ination
measured on a 12-month basis was a little
above the Federal Open Market Committee’s
(FOMC) longer-run objective of 2percent,
boosted by a sizable increase in energy prices.
In this economic environment, the Committee
judged that current and prospective economic
conditions called for a further gradual removal
of monetary policy accommodation. In line
with that judgment, the FOMC raised the
target for the federal funds rate twice in the
rst half of 2018, bringing it to a range of
1¾to 2percent.
Economic and Financial
Developments
The labor market. The labor market has
continued to strengthen. Over the rst
six months of 2018, payrolls increased an
average of 215,000 per month, which is
somewhat above the average pace of 180,000
per month in 2017 and is considerably faster
than what is needed, on average, to provide
jobs for new entrants into the labor force.
The unemployment rate edged down from
4.1percent in December to 4.0percent in June,
which is about ½percentage point below the
median of FOMC participants’ estimates of
its longer-run normal level. Other measures
of labor utilization were consistent with a
tight labor market. However, hourly labor
compensation growth has been moderate,
likely held down in part by the weak pace of
productivity growth in recent years.
Ination. Consumer price ination, as
measured by the 12-month percentage change
in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures, moved up from a little below
the FOMC’s objective of 2percent at the end
of last year to 2.3percent in May, boosted by
a sizable increase in consumer energy prices.
The 12-month measure of ination that
excludes food and energy items (so-called core
ination), which historically has been a better
indicator of where overall ination will be in
the future than the total gure, was 2percent
in May. This reading was ½percentage point
above where it had been 12 months earlier, as
the unusually low readings from last year were
not repeated. Measures of longer-run ination
expectations have been generally stable.
Economic growth. Real gross domestic product
(GDP) is reported to have increased at an
annual rate of 2percent in the rst quarter
of 2018, and recent indicators suggest that
economic growth stepped up in the second
quarter. Gains in consumer spending slowed
early in the year, but they rebounded in
the spring, supported by strong job gains,
recent and past increases in household
wealth, favorable consumer sentiment, and
higher disposable income due in part to the
implementation of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act.
Business investment growth has remained
robust, and indexes of business sentiment have
been strong. Foreign economic growth has
remained solid, and net exports had a roughly
neutral eect on real U.S. GDP growth in the
rst quarter. However, activity in the housing
market has leveled o this year.
Financial conditions. Domestic nancial
conditions for businesses and households
have generally continued to support economic
growth. After rising steadily through 2017,
broad measures of equity prices are modestly
higher, on balance, from their levels at the end
of last year amid some bouts of heightened
volatility in nancial markets. While long-
term Treasury yields, mortgage rates, and
yields on corporate bonds have risen so far
this year, longer-term interest rates remain
low by historical standards, and corporate
bond issuance has continued at a moderate
pace. Moreover, most types of consumer loans
2 SUMMARY
remained widely available for households with
strong creditworthiness, and credit provided by
commercial banks continued to expand. The
foreign exchange value of the U.S. dollar has
appreciated somewhat against the currencies
of our trading partners this year, but it
remains below its level at the start of 2017.
Foreign nancial conditions remain generally
supportive of growth despite recent increases
in nancial stress in several emerging market
economies.
Financial stability. The U.S. nancial system
remains substantially more resilient than
during the decade before the nancial crisis.
Asset valuations continue to be elevated
despite declines since the end of 2017 in the
forward price-to-earnings ratio of equities and
the prices of corporate bonds. In the private
nonnancial sector, borrowing among highly
levered and lower-rated businesses remains
elevated, although the ratio of household
debt to disposable income continues to be
moderate. Vulnerabilities stemming from
leverage in the nancial sector remain low,
reecting in part strong capital positions
at banks, whereas some measures of hedge
fund leverage have increased. Vulnerabilities
associated with maturity and liquidity
transformation among banks, insurance
companies, money market mutual funds,
and asset managers remain below levels that
generally prevailed before2008.
Monetary Policy
Interest rate policy. Over the rst half of 2018,
the FOMC has continued to gradually increase
the target range for the federal funds rate.
Specically, the Committee decided to raise
the target range for the federal funds rate at
its meetings in March and June, bringing it
to the current range of 1¾ to 2percent. The
decisions to increase the target range for the
federal funds rate reected the economy’s
continued progress toward the Committee’s
objectives of maximum employment and price
stability. Even with these policy rate increases,
the stance of monetary policy remains
accommodative, thereby supporting strong
labor market conditions and a sustained return
to 2percent ination.
The FOMC expects that further gradual
increases in the target range for the federal
funds rate will be consistent with a sustained
expansion of economic activity, strong labor
market conditions, and ination near the
Committee’s symmetric 2percent objective
over the medium term. Consistent with this
outlook, in the most recent Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP), which was
compiled at the time of the June FOMC
meeting, the median of participants’
assessments for the appropriate level for
the federal funds rate rises gradually over
the period from 2018 to 2020 and stands
somewhat above the median projection for
its longer-run level by the end of 2019 and
through 2020. (The June SEP is presented
in Part 3 of this report.) However, as the
Committee has continued to emphasize, the
timing and size of future adjustments to the
target range for the federal funds rate will
depend on the Committee’s assessment of
realized and expected economic conditions
relative to its maximum-employment objective
and its symmetric 2percent ination objective.
Balance sheet policy. The FOMC has
continued to implement the balance sheet
normalization program described in the
Addendum to the Policy Normalization
Principles and Plans that the Committee issued
about a year ago. Specically, the FOMC has
been reducing its holdings of Treasury and
agency securities by decreasing, in a gradual
and predictable manner, the reinvestment
of principal payments it receives from these
securities.
Special Topics
Prime-age labor force participation. Labor
force participation rates (LFPRs) for men and
women between 25 and 54years old—that is,
the share of these individuals either working
or actively seeking work—trended lower
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 3
between 2000 and 2013. Those trends likely
reect numerous factors, including a long-run
decline in the demand for workers with lower
levels of education and an increase in the
share of the population with some form of
disability. By contrast, the prime-age LFPR
has increased notably since 2013, and the
share of nonparticipants who report wanting
a job remains above pre-recession levels. Thus,
some continuation of the recent increase in
the prime-age LFPR may be possible if labor
demand remains strong. (See the box “The
Labor Force Participation Rate for Prime-Age
Individuals” in Part 1.)
Oil prices. Oil prices have climbed rapidly
over the past year, reecting both supply and
demand factors. Although higher oil prices
are likely to restrain household consumption
in the United States, much of the negative
eect on GDP from lower consumer spending
is likely to be oset by increased production
and investment in the growing U.S. oil sector.
Consequently, higher oil prices now imply
much less of a net overall drag on the economy
than they did in the past, although they will
continue to have important distributional
eects. The negative eect of upward moves
in oil prices should get smaller still as U.S. oil
production grows and net oil imports decline
further. (See the box “The Recent Rise in Oil
Prices” in Part 1.)
Monetary policy rules. Monetary policymakers
consider a wide range of information on
current economic conditions and the outlook
when deciding on a policy stance they deem
most likely to foster the FOMC’s statutory
mandate of maximum employment and stable
prices. They also routinely consult monetary
policy rules that connect prescriptions for the
policy interest rate with variables associated
with the dual mandate. The use of such rules
requires, among other considerations, careful
judgments about the choice and measurement
of the inputs into the rules such as estimates
of the neutral interest rate, which are highly
uncertain. (See the box “Complexities of
Monetary Policy Rules” in Part 2.)
Interest on reserves. The payment of interest
on reserves—balances held by banks in
their accounts at the Federal Reserve—is an
essential tool for implementing monetary
policy because it helps anchor the federal
funds rate within the FOMC’s target range.
This tool has permitted the FOMC to achieve
a gradual increase in the federal funds rate in
combination with a gradual reduction in the
Fed’s securities holdings and in the supply
of reserve balances. The FOMC judged that
removing monetary policy accommodation
through rst raising the federal funds rate
and then beginning to shrink the balance
sheet would best contribute to achieving and
maintaining maximum employment and
price stability without causing dislocations in
nancial markets or institutions that could put
the economic expansion at risk. (See the box
“Interest on Reserves and Its Importance for
Monetary Policy” in Part 2.)
5
Domestic Developments
The labor market strengthened further
during the rst half of the year . . .
Labor market conditions have continued to
strengthen so far in 2018. According to the
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), gains in
total nonfarm payroll employment averaged
215,000 per month over the rst half of the
year. That pace is up from the average monthly
pace of job gains in 2017 and is considerably
faster than what is needed to provide jobs for
new entrants into the labor force (gure1).
1
Indeed, the unemployment rate edged down
from 4.1percent in December to 4.0percent
in June (gure2). This rate is below all
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
participants’ estimates of its longer-run
normal level and is about ½percentage point
below the median of those estimates.
2
The
unemployment rate in June is close to the lows
last reached in 2000.
The labor force participation rate (LFPR),
which is the share of individuals aged 16
and older who are either working or actively
looking for work, was 62.9percent in June
and has changed little, on net, since late
2013 (gure3). The aging of the population
is an important contributor to a downward
trend in the overall participation rate. In
particular, members of the baby-boom
cohort are increasingly moving into their
retirement years, a time when labor force
participation is typically low. Indeed, the
share of the civilian population aged 65
and over in the United States climbed from
16percent in 2000 to 19percent in 2017 and
is projected to rise to 24percent by 2026.
Given this trend, the at trajectory of the
1. Monthly job gains in the range of 130,000 to
160,000 are consistent with an unchanged unemployment
rate and an unchanged labor force participation rate.
2. See the Summary of Economic Projections in Part3
of this report.
Part 1
recent economic and financiaL deveLoPments
Total nonfarm
800
600
400
200
+
_
0
200
400
Thousands of jobs
2018201720162015201420132012201120102009
1. Net change in payroll employment
3-month moving averages
Private
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
6 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
LFPR during the past few years is consistent
with strengthening labor market conditions.
Similarly, the LFPR for individuals between
25 and 54years old—which is much less
sensitive to population aging—has been rising
for the past several years. (The box “The
Labor Force Participation Rate for Prime-
Age Individuals” examines the prospects for
further increases in participation for these
individuals.) The employment-to-population
ratio for individuals 16 and over—the share
of the total population who are working—
was 60.4percent in June and has been
gradually increasing since 2011, reecting the
combination of the declining unemployment
rate and the at LFPR.
Other indicators are also consistent with
a strong labor market. As reported in the
Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), the rate of job openings has
remained quite elevated.
3
The rate of quits has
3. Indeed, the number of job openings now about
matches the number of unemployed individuals.
Employment-to-population ratio
Prime-age labor force
participation rate
56
58
60
62
64
66
68
Percent
80
81
82
83
84
85
20182015201220092006
3. Labor force participation rates and
employment-to-population ratio
Percent
Labor force participation rate
NOTE: The data are monthly. The prime-age labor force participation
rate
is a percentage of the population aged 25 to 54. The labor force
participation
rate and the employment-to-population ratio are percentages of the
population
aged 16 and over.
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
U-5
U-4
U-6
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006
2. Measures of labor underutilization
Monthly
Unemployment rate
N
OTE
: Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. U-4 measures total unemployed plus discouraged workers, as
a
percentage of the labor force plus discouraged workers. Discouraged workers are a subset of marginally attached workers who are not currently looking for work
because they believe no jobs are available for them. U-5 measures total unemployed plus all marginally attached to the labor force, as a percentage of the
labor
force plus persons marginally attached to the labor force. Marginally attached workers are not in the labor force, want and are
available for work, and have looked
for a job in the past 12 months. U-6 measures total unemployed plus all marginally attached workers plus total employed part time for economic reasons, as
a
percentage of the labor force plus all marginally attached workers. The shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau
of
Economic Research.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 7
stayed high in the JOLTS, an indication that
workers are able to successfully switch jobs
when they wish to. In addition, the JOLTS
layo rate has been low, and the number of
people ling initial claims for unemployment
insurance benets has remained near its
lowest level in decades. Other survey evidence
indicates that households perceive jobs as
plentiful and that businesses see vacancies as
hard to ll. Another indicator, the share of
workers who are working part time but would
prefer to be employed full time—which is part
of the U-6 measure of labor underutilization
from the BLS—fell further in the rst six
months of the year and now stands close to its
pre-recession level (as shown in gure2).
. . . and unemployment rates have fallen
for all major demographic groups
The continued decline in the unemployment
rate has been reected in the experiences of
multiple racial and ethnic groups (gure4).
The unemployment rates for blacks or
African Americans and Hispanics tend to
rise considerably more than rates for whites
and Asians during recessions but decline
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006
4. Unemployment rate by race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE: Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. Persons whose ethnicity is identified as Hispanic or Latino may be of
any race. The shaded bar indicates a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
8 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
increases in automation, such as the use of robotics,
and various aspects of globalization have spurred
the elimination of some types of jobs—in particular,
some manufacturing jobs that have historically been
held by workers without a college education—and
emerging jobs may require a different set of skills. These
developments may have led some workers to become
discouraged over the lack of suitable job opportunities
and drop out of the labor force.
1
The rising share of
college-educated workers, which may partly reect
individuals responding over time to the declining
demand for jobs that require less education, has likely
prevented even steeper declines in the prime-age LFPR,
as better-educated workers have higher LFPRs and
may be more adaptable to unforeseen disruptions in
particular jobs or industries.
Another potential factor may be that an increasing
share of the prime-age population has some difculty
working because of physical or mental disabilities.
For example, gure C shows that about 5percent of
both prime-age men and women report that they are
out of the labor force and do not want a job due to
disability or illness; those shares have trended higher
over the past several decades. Other research suggests
that increased opioid use may be associated with a
lower prime-age LFPR, although it is unclear how
much of the decline in the prime-age LFPR can be
directly explained by opioid use or whether increases
The overall labor force participation rate (LFPR) has
generally been trending lower since 2000, and while
the aging of the baby-boom generation into retirement
ages provides an important reason for that decline,
it is not the only reason. Another contributing factor,
as shown in gureA, is that the LFPRs of prime-age
men and women (those between 25 and 54years
old) trended lower through 2013 even though prime-
age LFPRs are largely unaffected by the aging of
the population: The prime-age male LFPR has been
declining for six decades, and the prime-age female
LFPR has drifted lower since 2000 after a multidecade
increase. Nevertheless, prime-age LFPRs have moved
up notably and consistently since 2013, as improving
labor market conditions have drawn some individuals
back into the labor force and encouraged others not to
leave. These recent increases in the prime-age LFPR,
in the context of the longer-run trend decline, raise the
question of how much additional scope there is for
further increases in prime-age labor force participation.
To gauge whether further increases are possible, a
useful starting point is understanding the factors behind
the longer-run decline in the prime-age LFPR, as these
factors may limit additional increases if they continue
to exert some downward pressure. One factor may
be a secular decline in the demand for workers with
lower levels of education. Indeed, as shown in gureB,
the long-run declines in prime-age LFPR are much
larger among adults without a college degree than
among college-educated adults. Research suggests that
The Labor Force Participation Rate for Prime-Age Individuals
Men
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
Percent
201820132008200319981993198819831978
A. Prime-age labor force participation rates
Monthly
Women
N
OTE: The data are seasonally adjusted. The shaded bars indicate
periods
of
business recession as defined by the National Bureau of
Economic
Research.
S
OURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
1. For evidence on displacement from technological
changes, see David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H.
Hanson (2015), “Untangling Trade and Technology: Evidence
from Local Labor Markets,Economic Journal, vol.125 (May),
pp. 621–46; Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo (2017),
“Robots and Jobs: Evidence from U.S. Labor Markets,” NBER
Working Paper Series 23285 (Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research, March), www.nber.org/
papers/w23285; and Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo
(2018), “Articial Intelligence, Automation, and Work,” NBER
Working Paper Series 24196 (Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research, January), www.nber.org/
papers/w24196. For evidence on globalization—in particular,
import competition since the 2000s—see David H. Autor,
David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson (2013), “The China
Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition
in the United States,American Economic Review, vol. 103
(October), pp. 2121–68. A discussion of these and other
explanations is also provided in Katharine G. Abraham and
Melissa S. Kearney (2018), “Explaining the Decline in the U.S.
Employment-to-Population Ratio: A Review of the Evidence,
NBER Working Paper Series 24333 (Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research, February), www.nber.
org/papers/w24333.
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 9
responsibilities as women participate in the workforce
in greater numbers. For some—especially those for
whom childcare costs are not a major concern—not
participating in the labor force may represent an
unconstrained choice to care for other members of their
families. For others, however, this decision may reect
a lack of affordable childcare.
Additionally, the share of the population—
particularly black men—with a history of incarceration
has increased over time. Individuals who have
previously been incarcerated often have trouble nding
work, in part because many employers choose not to
hire people with such a background and likely also
in part because incarceration prevents people from
accumulating work experience and developing skills
valuable to employers. Discrimination could also help
explain the lack of participation for some minority
groups, as they recognize that such discrimination
limits their job opportunities.
International comparisons may help clarify the
importance of some of those factors. Since 1990, the
in opioid use are an indirect result of poor employment
opportunities.
2
Caregiving responsibilities play an important role in
explaining why LFPRs for prime-age women are lower
than for men, and they may play an increasing role in
explaining declining prime-age LFPRs for men as well.
As shown in gure C, roughly 15percent of prime-
age women report being out of the labor force for
caregiving reasons—by far the largest reason for prime-
age women to report not wanting a job—but this share
has been fairly at over time. In contrast, while a much
smaller fraction of men are out of the labor force for
caregiving reasons, that share has trended up in recent
decades, likely reecting some shift in household
2. Evidence that opioid use could be signicant for
understanding the declining LFPR is provided by Alan B.
Krueger (2017), “Where Have All the Workers Gone? An
Inquiry into the Decline of the U.S. Labor Force Participation
Rate,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, pp. 1–82,
https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/02/
kruegertextfa17bpea.pdf, while little relationship between
opioid prescriptions and employment at the county level is
found in Janet Currie, Jonas Y. Jin, and Molly Schnell (2018),
“U.S. Employment and Opioids: Is There a Connection?”
NBER Working Paper Series 24440 (Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research, March), www.nber.
org/papers/w24440. Some evidence on whether the opioid
epidemic varies with local economic conditions is provided
by Jeff Larrimore, Alex Durante, Kimberly Kreiss, Ellen Merry,
Women
Men
B. Prime-age labor force participation rates by education
N: The data are seasonally adjusted 12-month moving averages and extend through May 2018. The shaded bars indicate
periods of business recession as dened by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
S: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey.
Monthly PercentMonthly Percent
Bachelor's degree
High school degree or less 82
86
90
94
98
201820132008200319981993198819831978
Some college
Bachelor's degree
High school degree or less
50
55
60
65
70
75
80
85
201820132008200319981993198819831978
Some college
Christina Park, and Claudia Sahm (2018), “Shedding Light on
Our Economic and Financial Lives,” FEDS Notes, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/shedding-light-on-
our-economic-and-nancial-lives-20180522.htm.
(continued on next page)
10 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
self-report as wanting a job (despite not having actively
searched for a job recently) has been declining since
2010, that share for men remains between ¼ and
½percentage point above its 2007 level and earlier
expansion peaks. Furthermore, prime-age men and
women who had previously reported being out of the
labor force and not wanting a job due to disability or
illness have been entering the labor force at increasing
rates in recent years.
Looking forward, how can policymakers support
additional improvements in the prime-age LFPR?
Favorable labor market conditions can likely help,
and monetary policy can therefore play a role through
supporting strong cyclical conditions as part of its
maximum-employment objective. However, structural
factors (in contrast with cyclical ones) are also
important to address; policies to address such factors
are beyond the scope of monetary policy.
prime-age LFPR in the United States has declined
considerably for both men and women relative to other
advanced countries. Some factors, like automation and
globalization, have affected all advanced economies to
some degree and for some time, yet diverging long-run
trends in prime-age labor force participation have still
occurred. Research suggests that part of the relative
decline in the United States is explained by differential
changes in work-family policies across countries.
Other parts of the divergence may be explained by
other policies, including policies designed toward
keeping those affected by automation and globalization
attached to the labor force, or other factors—such as
incarceration or opioid use—that differ across those
countries.
3
Although many of the factors behind the
multidecade decline in the prime-age LFPR may
persist, some continuation of the increases in the LFPR
over the past few years nevertheless seems possible,
especially if labor market conditions remain favorable.
Indeed, as shown in gure C, although the share of
nonparticipating prime-age men and women who
3. For recent trends on prime-age LFPRs in the United
States compared with other developed countries, see
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(2018), OECD Economic Surveys: United States 2018 (Paris:
OECD Publishing), dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-usa-2018-
en. For a description of policy differences across countries
Disabled
Caregiving
Wants job
2018201420102006200219981994
Other, does not want job
Disabled
Caregiving
Wants job
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2018201420102006200219981994
Other, does not want job
PercentMonthly Monthly Percent
N: The data are seasonally adjusted 12-month moving averages and extend through May 2018. The shaded bars indicate
Women
The Labor Force Participation Rate (continued)
and how this may affect differences in LFPR, see International
Monetary Fund (2018), “Labor Force Participation in Advanced
Economies: Drivers and Prospects,” chapter 2 in World
Economic Outlook: Cyclical Upswing, Structural Change
(Washington: IMF, April), pp.71–128. For evidence on how
work-family policies may affect prime-age LFPRs in the United
States relative to other OECD countries, see Francine D. Blau
and LawrenceM. Kahn (2013), “Female Labor Supply: Why
Is the United States Falling Behind?” American Economic
Review, vol. 103 (May), pp. 251–56.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 11
more rapidly during expansions. Indeed,
the declines in the unemployment rates for
blacks and Hispanics have been particularly
striking, and the rates have recently been at
or near their lowest readings since these series
began in the early 1970s. Although dierences
in unemployment rates across ethnic and
racial groups have narrowed in recent years,
they remain substantial and similar to pre-
recession levels. The rise in LFPRs for prime-
age individuals over the past few years has
also been evident in each of these racial and
ethnic groups, with increases again particularly
notable for African Americans. Even so, the
LFPR for whites remains higher than that for
the other groups (gure5).
4
Increases in labor compensation have
been moderate . . .
Despite the strong labor market, the available
indicators generally suggest that increases
in hourly labor compensation have been
moderate. Compensation per hour in the
business sector—a broad-based measure
of wages, salaries, and benets that is quite
volatile—rose 2¾percent over the four
quarters ending in 2018:Q1, slightly more than
the average annual increase over the preceding
seven or so years (gure6). The employment
cost index—a less volatile measure of both
wages and the cost to employers of providing
benets—likewise was 2¾percent higher in
the rst quarter of 2018 relative to its year-
earlier level; this increase was ½percentage
point faster than its gain a year earlier. Among
measures that do not account for benets,
average hourly earnings rose 2¾percent in
June relative to 12months earlier, a gain in
line with the average increase in the preceding
few years. According to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta, the median 12-month wage
4. The lower levels of labor force participation for
these other groups dier importantly by sex. For African
Americans, men have a lower participation rate relative
to white men, while the participation rate for African
American women is as high as that of white women. By
contrast, the lower LFPRs for Hispanics and Asians
reect lower participation among women.
Employment cost index
Atlanta Fed's
Wage Growth Tracker
Average hourly earnings
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent change from year earlier
20182016201420122010
6. Measures of change in hourly compensation
Compensation per hour,
business sector
N
OTE
: Business-sector compensation is on a 4-quarter percentage
change
basis. For the employment cost index, change is over the 12 months ending in
the last month of each quarter; for average hourly earnings, change is from
12
months earlier; for the Atlanta Fed's Wage Growth Tracker, the data
are
shown as a 3-month moving average of the 12-month percent change
and
extend through May 2018.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics; Federal
Reserve
Bank of Atlanta, Wage Growth Tracker.
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006
5. Prime-age labor force participation rate by race and
ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE
: The prime-age labor force participation rate is a percentage of the
population aged 25 to 54. Persons whose ethnicity is identified as Hispanic or
Latino may be of any race. The data are seasonally adjusted by Board staff
and are 3-month moving averages. The shaded bar indicates a period of
business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
12 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
growth of individuals reporting to the Current
Population Survey increased about 3¼percent
in May, also similar to its readings from the
past few years.
5
. . . and likely have been restrained by
slow growth of labor productivity
Those moderate rates of compensation
gains likely reect the osetting inuences
of a strong labor market and persistently
weak productivity growth. Since 2008, labor
productivity has increased only a little more
than 1percent per year, on average, well below
the average pace from 1996 through 2007 of
2.8percent and also below the average gain in
the 1974–95 period of 1.6percent (gure7).
The weakness in productivity growth may
be partly attributable to the sharp pullback
in capital investment during the most recent
recession and the relatively slow recovery
that followed. However, considerable debate
remains about the reasons for the recent
slowdown in productivity growth and whether
it will persist.
6
Price ination has picked up from the
low readings in 2017
In 2017, ination remained below the FOMC’s
longer-run objective of 2percent. Partly
because the softness in some price categories
appeared idiosyncratic, Federal Reserve
policymakers expected ination to move
higher in 2018.
7
This expectation appears to be
5. The Atlanta Fed’s measure diers from others in
that it measures the wage growth only of workers who
were employed both in the current survey month and
12months earlier.
6. The box “Productivity Developments in the
Advanced Economies” in the July2017 Monetary
Policy Report provides more information. See Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2017),
Monetary Policy Report (Washington: Board of
Governors, July), pp. 12–13, https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/2017-07-mpr-part1.htm.
7. Additional details can be found in the June2017
Summary of Economic Projections, an addendum to the
minutes of the June2017 FOMC meeting. See Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2017),
“Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee,
1
2
3
4
Percent, annual rate
7. Change in business-sector output per hour
1948–
73
1974–
95
1996–
2000
2001–
07
2008–
present
NOTE
: Changes are measured from Q4 of the year immediately
preceding
the period through Q4 of the final year of the period. The final period
is
measured from 2007:Q4 through 2018:Q1.
SOURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 13
on track so far. Consumer price ination, as
measured by the 12-month percentage change
in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures (PCE), moved up to 2.3percent
in May (gure8). Core PCE ination, which
excludes consumer food and energy prices that
are often quite volatile and typically provides
a better indication than the total measure of
where overall ination will be in the future,
was 2percent over the 12months ending in
May—0.5percentage point higher than it
had been one year earlier. The total measure
exceeded core ination because of a sizable
increase in consumer energy prices. In
contrast, food price ination has continued to
be low by historical standards—data through
May show the PCE price index for food and
beverages having increased less than ½percent
over the past year.
The higher readings in both total and core
ination relative to a year earlier reect faster
price increases for a wide range of goods and
services this year and the dropping out of the
12-month calculation of the steep one-month
decline in the price index for wireless telephone
services in March last year. The 12-month
change in the trimmed mean PCE price
index—an alternative indicator of underlying
ination produced by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas that may be less sensitive
than the core index to idiosyncratic price
movements—slowed by less than core ination
over 2017 and has also increased a bit less
this year. This index rose 1.8percent over the
12months ending in May, up a touch from the
increase over the same period last year.
8
June13–14, 2017, press release, July5, https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20170705a.htm.
8. The trimmed mean index excludes whatever prices
showed the largest increases or decreases in a given
month; for example, the sharp decline in prices for
wireless telephone services in March2017 was excluded
from this index.
Excluding food
and energy
Trimmed mean
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
12-month percent change
20182017201620152014201320122011
8. Change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures
Monthly
Total
NOTE
: The data extend through May 2018; changes are from one year
earlier.
SOURCE: For trimmed mean, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; for all else,
Bureau of Economic Analysis; all via Haver Analytics.
14 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Oil prices have surged amid supply
concerns . . .
As noted, the faster pace of total ination
this year relative to core ination reects a
substantial rise in consumer energy prices.
Retail gasoline prices this year were driven
higher by a rise in oil prices. The spot price of
Brent crude oil rose from about $65 per barrel
in December to around $75per barrel in early
July (gure9). Although that increase took
place against a backdrop of continued strength
in global demand, supply concerns have
become more prevalent in recent months. (For
a discussion of the reasons behind the oil price
increases along with a review of the eects of
oil prices on U.S. economic growth, see the
box “The Recent Rise in Oil Prices.”)
. . . while prices of imports other than
energy have also increased
Nonfuel import prices rose sharply in early
2018, partly reecting the pass-through
of earlier increases in commodity prices
(gure10). In particular, metals prices posted
sizable gains late last year due to strong
global demand but have retreated somewhat
in recent weeks.
Survey-based measures of ination
expectations have been stable . . .
Expectations of ination likely inuence actual
ination by aecting wage- and price-setting
decisions. Survey-based measures of ination
expectations at medium- and longer-term
horizons have remained generally stable so
far this year. In the Survey of Professional
Forecasters conducted by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, the median expectation
for the annual rate of increase in the PCE
price index over the next 10years has been
around 2percent for the past several years
(gure11). In the University of Michigan
Surveys of Consumers, the median value
for ination expectations over the next 5 to
10years has been about 2½percent since
the end of 2016, though this level is about
¼percentage point lower than had prevailed
through 2014. In contrast, in the Survey of
Consumer Expectations conducted by the
Nonfuel import prices
94
96
98
100
102
July 2014 = 100
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
2018201720162015201420132012
10. Nonfuel import prices and industrial metals indexes
July 2014 = 100
Industrial metals
N
OTE
: The data for nonfuel import prices are monthly and extend through
May
2018. The data for industrial metals are a monthly average of daily data
and extend through June 29, 2018.
SOURCE
: For nonfuel import prices, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for
industrial
metals, S&P GSCI Industrial Metals Spot Index via Haver
Analytics.
Spot price
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
120
130
Dollars per barrel
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
9. Brent spot and futures prices
Weekly
24-month-ahead
futures contracts
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend
through
July 11, 2018.
S
OURCE: ICE Brent Futures via Bloomberg.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 15
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the
median of respondents’ expected ination rate
three years hence has been moving up recently
and is currently at the top of the range it has
occupied over the past couple of years.
. . . while market-based measures of
ination compensation have largely
moved sideways this year
Ination expectations can also be gauged
by market-based measures of ination
compensation. However, the inference
is not straightforward, because market-
based measures can be importantly aected
by changes in premiums that provide
compensation for bearing ination and
liquidity risks. Measures of longer-term
ination compensation—derived either from
dierences between yields on nominal Treasury
securities and those on comparable-maturity
Treasury Ination-Protected Securities
(TIPS) or from ination swaps—have moved
sideways for the most part this year after
having returned to levels seen in early 2017
(gure12).
9
The TIPS-based measure of
5-to-10-year-forward ination compensation
and the analogous measure of ination swaps
are now about 2percent and 2½percent,
respectively, with both measures below the
ranges that persisted for most of the 10years
before the start of the notable declines in
mid-2014.
10
9. Ination compensation implied by the TIPS
breakeven ination rate is based on the dierence, at
comparable maturities, between yields on nominal
Treasury securities and yields on TIPS, which are indexed
to the total consumer price index (CPI). Ination swaps
are contracts in which one party makes payments of
certain xed nominal amounts in exchange for cash
ows that are indexed to cumulative CPI ination over
some horizon. Focusing on ination compensation 5 to
10years ahead is useful, particularly for monetary policy,
because such forward measures encompass market
participants’ views about where ination will settle in the
long term after developments inuencing ination in the
short term have run their course.
10. As these measures are based on CPI ination,
one should probably subtract about ¼ to ½percentage
point—the average dierential with PCE ination over
the past two decades—to infer ination compensation on
a PCE basis.
Michigan survey expectations
for next 5 to 10 years
1
2
3
4
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006
SPF expectations
for next 10 years
11. Median inflation expectations
NOTE
: The Michigan survey data are monthly. The SPF data for
inflation
expectations for personal consumption expenditures are quarterly and
extend
from 2007:Q1 through 2018:Q2.
S
OURCE: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal
Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF).
Inflation swaps
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Percent
20182016201420122010
12. 5-to-10-year-forward inflation compensation
Weekly
TIPS breakeven rates
N
OTE:The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend
through
July 6, 2018. TIPS is Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Barclays; Federal
Reserve
Board staff estimates.
16 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
the country’s economic and political crisis. Prices also
increased after President Trump announced on May8
that the United States was withdrawing from the Iran
nuclear deal and that sanctions against Iranian oil
exports would be reinstated.
The pattern of spot and futures prices indicates
that market participants generally anticipate that oil
prices will decline slowly over the next few years, in
part reecting an expectation that supply, including
U.S. shale oil production, will grow to meet demand.
In addition, the higher prices put pressure on OPEC’s
November2016 agreement with certain non-OPEC
countries to restrain production. A stated aim of the
agreement was to reduce the glut in global inventories,
and, in recent months, inventory levels have fallen
rapidly toward long-run averages. In response to both
lower inventories and higher prices, OPEC leaders
slightly relaxed the production agreement in June this
Oil prices have increased more than 50percent
over the past year, with the spot price of Brent crude
oil rising from a bit below $50per barrel to around
$75per barrel (gureA). For much of the period,
further-dated futures prices remained relatively stable,
in the neighborhood of $55per barrel; however, since
February, futures prices have moved up appreciably,
reaching over $70per barrel.
Both supply and demand factors have contributed
to the oil price increase. In particular, the broad-based
improvement in the outlook for the global economy
was a key driver of the price increase in the second
half of 2017. In recent months, supply concerns have
become more prevalent, affecting both spot and further-
dated futures prices. Despite sharply rising U.S. oil
production, markets have been attuned to escalating
conict between Saudi Arabia and Iran as well as the
precipitous decline in Venezuelan oil production amid
The Recent Rise in Oil Prices
Spot price
40
50
60
70
80
90
Dollars per barrel
Jan. Mar. May July Sept. Nov. Jan. Mar. May July
20182017
Daily
December 2019 futures price
OURCE
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 17
power abroad than in the past, as much of the negative
effect on GDP from lower household consumption
is likely to be offset by increased production and
investment in the growing U.S. oil sector. On net, the
drag on GDP from higher oil prices is likely a small
fraction of what it was a decade ago and should get
smaller still if U.S. oil production continues to grow
as projected—gure C—and the net oil import share
shrinks toward zero.
Indeed, if U.S. oil trade moves fully into balance,
the offsetting effects of a change in the relative price of
oil might be expected to net out within the domestic
economy. However, even if the United States is no
longer a net oil importer, to the extent that higher
oil prices cause credit-constrained consumers to cut
spending by more than oil producers expand their
investment, this redistribution of purchasing power
could still have negative effects on overall GDP.
year, reducing some of the upward pressure on prices.
That said, futures prices have not returned to their early
2018 levels, implying that market participants expect
some of the recent increase in prices to be long lasting.
What is the expected effect of the recent rise in oil
prices on the U.S. economy? To begin with, higher oil
prices are likely to restrain household consumption.
In particular, the increase in oil prices since last year
is estimated to have translated into a roughly $300
increase in annual expenditures on gasoline for the
average household, from about $2,100 to $2,400.
However, as U.S. oil production has grown rapidly
over the past decade, the ratio of net U.S. oil imports
to U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) has declined
substantially (gure B). As a result, higher oil prices
now imply much less of a redistribution of purchasing
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
Percent of nominal GDP
2019201720152013201120092007200520032001
B. Net oil import share
Quarterly
NOTE:
The data extending through 2018:Q1 are quarterly averages of daily
oil
futures prices, quarterly averages of monthly oil imports and exports,
and
quarterly
GDP. The data from 2018:Q2 through 2019:Q4 are
projections
based
on quarterly averages of monthly oil futures prices, quarterly
averages
of monthly oil imports and exports, and quarterly GDP.
SOURCE: Department of Energy via Haver Analytics; ICE Brent Futures
via
Bloomberg; Bureau of Economic Analysis; staff calculations.
8
9
10
11
12
13
Million barrels per day
201920182017201620152014
C. U.S. crude oil production
Quarterly
NOTE: The data are quarterly averages of monthly data. The data
extend
through 2018:Q2. Data from 2018:Q3 through 2019:Q4 are projections.
S
OURCE
: Department of Energy via Haver Analytics.
18 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Real gross domestic product growth
slowed in the rst quarter, but spending
by households appears to have picked up
in recent months
After having expanded at an annual rate of
3percent in the second half of 2017, real gross
domestic product (GDP) is now reported to
have increased 2percent in the rst quarter of
this year (gure13). The step-down in growth
during the rst quarter was largely attributable
to a sharp slowing in the growth of consumer
spending that appears transitory, and gains in
GDP appear to have rebounded in the second
quarter. Meanwhile, business investment has
remained strong, and net exports had little
eect on output growth in the rst quarter. On
balance, over the rst half of this year, overall
economic activity appears to have expanded at
a solid pace.
The economic expansion continues to be
supported by favorable consumer and business
sentiment, past increases in household
wealth, solid economic growth abroad, and
accommodative domestic nancial conditions,
including moderate borrowing costs and easy
access to credit for many households and
businesses.
Gains in income and wealth continue to
support consumer spending . . .
Following exceptionally strong growth in the
fourth quarter of 2017, consumer spending
in the rst quarter of this year was tepid,
rising at an annual rate of 0.9percent. The
slowdown in growth was evident in outlays
for motor vehicles and in retail sales more
generally; moreover, unseasonably warm
weather depressed spending on energy services.
However, consumer spending picked up in
more recent months as retail sales rmed, and
PCE in April and May rose at an annual rate
of 2¼percent relative to the average over the
rst quarter (gure14).
Real disposable personal income (DPI), a
measure of after-tax income adjusted for
ination, has increased at a solid annual rate
of about 3percent so far this year. Real DPI
3
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent, annual rate
2018201720162015201420132012
14. Change in real personal consumption expenditures
and disposable personal income
H1
NOTE
: The values for 2018:H1 are the annualized May/Q4 changes.
SOURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Personal consumption expenditures
Disposable personal income
2
4
6
8
10
12
PercentMonthly
2018201620142012201020082006
15. Personal saving rate
NOTE
: Data are through May 2018.
S
OURCE
:Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
1
2
3
4
5
Percent, annual rate
20182017201620152014201320122011
13. Change in real gross domestic product and gross
domestic income
Q1
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 19
has been supported by the reduction in income
taxes owing to the implementation of the
Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) as well as the
continued strength in the labor market. With
consumer spending rising just a little less than
the gains in disposable income so far this year,
the personal saving rate has edged up after
having fallen for the past two years (gure15).
Ongoing gains in household net worth likely
have also supported consumer spending.
House prices, which are of particular
importance for the balance sheet positions of
a large set of households, have been increasing
at an average annual pace of about 6percent in
recent years (gure16).
11
Although U.S. equity
prices have posted modest gains, on net, so far
this year, this attening followed several years
of sizable gains. Buoyed by the cumulative
increases in home and equity prices, aggregate
household net worth was 6.8times household
income in the rst quarter, down just slightly
from its ratio in the fourth quarter—the
highest-ever reading for that ratio, which dates
back to 1947 (gure17).
. . . and borrowing conditions for
consumers remain generally favorable . . .
Financing conditions for consumers are
generally favorable and remain supportive
of growth in household spending. However,
banks have continued to tighten standards
for credit cards and auto loans for borrowers
with low credit scores, possibly in response
to some upward moves in the delinquency
rates of those borrowers. Mortgage credit has
remained readily available for households with
solid credit proles. For borrowers with low
credit scores, mortgage nancing conditions
have eased somewhat further but remain tight
overall. In this environment, consumer credit
continued to increase in the rst few months
of 2018, though the rate of increase moderated
some from its robust pace in the previous year
(gure18).
11. For the majority of households, home equity
makes up the largest share of their wealth.
CoreLogic
price index
S&P/Case-Shiller
national index
20
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
Percent change from year earlier
201820162014201220102008
16. Prices of existing single-family houses
Monthly
Zillow index
N
OTE
: The data for the S&P/Case-Shiller index extend through April
2018.
The
data for the Zillow index and the CoreLogic index extend through
May
2018.
S
OURCE: CoreLogic Home Price Index; Zillow; S&P/Case-Shiller
U.S.
National Home Price Index. The S&P/Case-Shiller Index is a product of S&P
Dow
Jones Indices LLC and/or its affiliates. (For Dow Jones
Indices
licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
Ratio
2018201520122009200620032000
17. Wealth-to-income ratio
Quarterly
NOTE
: The series is the ratio of household net worth to disposable personal
income.
SOURCE: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release
Z.1,
“Financial
Accounts of the United States”; for income, Bureau of
Economic
Analysis via Haver Analytics.
600
400
200
+
_
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
Billions of dollars, annual rate
201820162014201220102008
18. Changes in household debt
Sum
Q1
NOTE
: Changes are calculated from year-end to year-end except
2018
changes, which are calculated from 2017:Q4 to 2018:Q1.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1,
“Financial
Accounts of the United States.”
Mortgages
Consumer credit
20 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
60
80
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
201820162014201220102008
21. Selected components of net debt financing for
nonfinancial businesses
Sum
Q1
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1,
“Financial
Accounts of the United States.”
Commercial paper
Bonds
Bank loans
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
Percent, annual rate
201820172016201520142013201220112010
20. Change in real private nonresidential fixed investment
Q1
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Structures
Equipment and intangible capital
. . . while consumer condence remains
strong
Consumers have remained upbeat. So far this
year, the Michigan survey index of consumer
sentiment has been near its highest level
since 2000, likely reecting rising income, job
gains, and low ination (gure19). Indeed,
households’ expectations for real income
changes over the next year or two now stand
above levels preceding the previous recession.
Business investment has continued
to rebound . . .
Investment spending by businesses has
continued to increase so far this year, with
notable gains for spending, both on equipment
and intangibles and on nonresidential
structures (gure20). Within structures,
the rise in oil prices propelled another steep
ramp-up in investment in drilling and mining
structures—albeit not yet back to the levels
recorded from 2012 to 2014—while investment
in nonresidential structures outside of the
energy sector picked up after declining in
2017. Forward-looking indicators of business
investment spending remain favorable on
balance. Business sentiment and the prot
expectations of industry analysts have been
positive overall, while new orders of capital
goods have advanced on net this year.
. . . while corporate nancing conditions
have remained accommodative
Aggregate ows of credit to large nonnancial
rms remained strong in the rst quarter,
supported in part by relatively low interest
rates and accommodative nancing conditions
(gure21). The gross issuance of corporate
bonds stayed robust during the rst half of
2018, while yields on both investment- and
speculative-grade corporate bonds moved
up notably but remained low by historical
standards (gure22). Despite strong growth in
business investment, outstanding commercial
and industrial (C&I) loans on banks’ books
rose only modestly in the rst quarter,
although their pace of expansion in more
recent months has strengthened on average. In
Consumer sentiment
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
Index
50
60
70
80
90
2018201620142012201020082006
Diffusion index
19. Indexes of consumer sentiment and income expectations
Real income expectations
N
OTE
: The consumer sentiment data are monthly and are indexed to 100 in
1966. The real income expectations data are calculated as the net percentage
of survey respondents expecting family income to go up more than prices
during the next year or two plus 100 and are shown as a three-month moving
average.
S
OURCE
: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 21
April, respondents to the Senior Loan Ocer
Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,
or SLOOS, reported that demand for C&I
loans weakened in the rst quarter even as
lending standards and terms on such loans
eased.
12
Respondents attributed this decline in
demand in part to rms drawing on internally
generated funds or using alternative sources of
nancing. Meanwhile, growth in commercial
real estate loans has moderated some but
remains strong. In addition, nancing
conditions for small businesses appear to
have remained generally accommodative, with
lending standards little changed at most banks
and with most rms reporting that they are
able to obtain credit. Although small business
credit growth has been subdued, survey data
suggest this sluggishness is largely due to
continued weak demand for credit by small
businesses.
But activity in the housing sector has
leveled off
Residential investment, which rose a modest
2½percent in 2017, appears to have largely
moved sideways over the rst ve months of
the year. The slowing in residential investment
likely is partly a result of higher mortgage
interest rates. Although these rates are still
low by historical standards, they have moved
up and are near their highest levels in seven
years (gure23). In addition, higher lumber
prices and tight supplies of skilled labor
and developed lots reportedly have been
restraining home construction. While starts
of both single-family and multifamily housing
units rose in the fourth quarter, single-family
starts have been little changed, on net, since
then, whereas multifamily starts continued
to climb earlier this year before attening
out (gure24). Meanwhile, over the rst ve
months of this year, new home sales have
held at around the rate of late last year, but
sales of existing homes have eased somewhat
(gure25). Despite the continued increases
in house prices, the pace of construction has
12. The SLOOS is available on the Board’s website at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/data/sloos/sloos.htm.
Double-A
High-yield
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Percentage points
2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018
22. Corporate bond yields, by securities rating
Daily
Triple-B
N
OTE: The yields shown are yields on 10-year bonds.
S
OURCE
: ICE Bank of America Merrill Lynch Indices, used
with
permission.
Mortgage rates
85
105
125
145
165
185
205
Index
3
4
5
6
7
20182016201420122010
23. Mortgage rates and housing affordability
Percent
Housing affordability index
N
OTE: The housing affordability index data are monthly
through
April
2018, and the mortgage rate data are weekly through July 5, 2018.
At
an index value of 100, a median-income family has exactly enough income to
qualify
for a median-priced home mortgage. Housing affordability
is
seasonally adjusted by Board staff.
SOURCE
: For housing affordability index, National Association of
Realtors;
for mortgage rates, Freddie Mac Primary Mortgage Market Survey.
Multifamily starts
Single-family permits
0
.4
.8
1.2
1.6
2.0
Millions of units, annual rate
2018201620142012201020082006
24. Private housing starts and permits
Monthly
Single-family starts
N
OTE
: The data extend through May 2018.
SOURCE
: U.S. Census Bureau via Haver Analytics.
22 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
not kept up with demand. As a result, the
months’ supply of inventories of homes for
sale has remained at a relatively low level, and
the aggregate vacancy rate stands at the lowest
level since 2003.
Net exports had a neutral effect on GDP
growth in the rst quarter
After being a small drag on U.S. real GDP
growth last year, net exports had a neutral
eect on growth in the rst quarter. Real
U.S. exports increased about 3½percent at
an annual rate, as exports of automobiles
and consumer goods remained robust. Real
import growth slowed sharply following
a surge late last year (gure26). Nominal
trade data through May suggest that export
growth picked up in the second quarter, led
by agricultural exports, while import growth
was tepid. All told, the available data suggest
that the nominal trade decit likely narrowed
relative to GDP in the second quarter
(gure27).
Fiscal policy became more expansionary
this year . . .
Federal scal policy will likely provide a
moderate boost to GDP growth this year. The
individual and corporate tax cuts in the TCJA
should lead to increased private consumption
and investment, while the Bipartisan Budget
Act of 2018 (BBA) enables increased federal
spending on goods and services. As the eects
of the BBA had yet to show through, federal
government purchases posted only a modest
gain in the rst quarter (gure28).
After narrowing signicantly for several years,
the federal unied decit widened from about
2½percent of GDP in scal year 2015 to
3½percent in scal 2017, and it is on pace
to move up further in scal 2018. Although
expenditures as a share of GDP in 2017
were relatively stable at 21percent, receipts
moved lower to roughly 17percent of GDP
and have remained at about the same level so
far this year (gure29). The ratio of federal
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
Percent, annual rate
2018201720162015201420132012
26. Change in real imports and exports of goods
and services
Q1
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Imports
Exports
Current account
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
+
_
0
Percent of nominal GDP
201820162014201220102008200620042002
27. U.S. trade and current account balances
Quarterly
Trade
N
OTE: GDP is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Existing home sales
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
Millions, annual rate
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
7.5
2018201620142012201020082006
25. New and existing home sales
Millions, annual rate
New home sales
N
OTE: Data are monthly and extend through May 2018. New home
sales
includes only single-family sales. Existing home sales includes single-family,
condo, townhome, and co-op sales.
S
OURCE: For new home sales, U.S. Census Bureau; for existing
home
sales, National Association of Realtors; all via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 23
debt held by the public to nominal GDP was
76½percent at the end of scal 2017 and is
quite elevated relative to historical norms
(gure30).
. . . and the scal position of most state
and local governments is stable
The scal position of most state and local
governments remains stable, although there is a
range of experiences across these governments
and some states are still struggling. After
several years of slow growth, revenue gains of
state governments have strengthened notably
as sales and income tax collections have picked
up over the past few quarters. In addition,
house price gains have continued to push up
property tax revenues at the local level. But
expenditures by state and local governments
have been restrained. Employment growth
in this sector has been moderate, while real
outlays for construction by these governments
have largely been moving sideways at a
relatively low level.
Financial Developments
The expected path of the federal funds
rate has moved up
Market-based measures of the path of the
federal funds rate continue to suggest that
market participants expect further gradual
increases in the federal funds rate. Relative
to the end of last year, the expected policy
rate path has moved up, boosted in part by
investors’ perception of a strengthening in
the domestic economic outlook (gure31).
In particular, the policy path moved higher
in response to incoming economic data so far
this year, especially the employment reports,
which were seen as supporting expectations for
a solid pace of growth in domestic economic
activity. In addition, investors reportedly
interpreted FOMC communications in the rst
half of 2018 as signaling an upbeat economic
outlook and as reinforcing expectations for
further gradual removal of monetary policy
accommodation.
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
Percent, annual rate
2018201720162015201420132012201120102009
28. Change in real government expenditures on
consumption and investment
Q1
SOURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Federal
State and local
Expenditures
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
Percent of nominal GDPPercent of nominal GDP
20182015201220092006200320001997
Annual
29. Federal receipts and expenditures
Receipts
N
OTE
: Through 2017, receipts and expenditures are for fiscal years
(October
to September); gross domestic product (GDP) is for the four
quarters
ending in Q3. For 2018, receipts and expenditures are for the
12
months ending in May; GDP is the average of 2017:Q4 and 2018:Q1.
Receipts and expenditures are on a unified-budget basis.
S
OURCE
: Office of Management and Budget via Haver Analytics.
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Percent of nominal GDP
Quarterly
30. Federal government debt held by the public
1968 1978 1988 1998 2008 2018
N
OTE: The data for gross domestic product (GDP) are at an annual rate.
Federal
debt held by the public equals federal debt less Treasury securities
held in federal employee defined benefit retirement accounts, evaluated at the
end of the quarter.
SOURCE
: For GDP, Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics; for
federal
debt, Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financial
Accounts of the United States.”
24 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Survey-based measures of the expected path
of the policy rate over the next few years have
also increased modestly since the end of last
year. According to the results of the most
recent Survey of Primary Dealers and Survey
of Market Participants, both conducted by
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York just
before the June FOMC meeting, the median
of respondents’ projections for the path of the
federal funds rate shifted up about 25 basis
points for 2018 and beyond, compared with
the median of assessments last December.
13
Market-based measures of uncertainty about
the policy rate approximately one to two years
ahead increased slightly, on balance, from their
levels at the end of last year.
The nominal Treasury yield curve has
shifted up
The nominal Treasury yield curve has shifted
up and attened somewhat further during the
rst half of 2018 after attening considerably
in the second half of 2017. In particular, the
yields on 2- and 10-year nominal Treasury
securities increased about 70 basis points and
45basis points, respectively, from their levels
at the end of 2017 (gure32). The increase
in Treasury yields seems to largely reect
investors’ greater optimism about the domestic
growth outlook and rming expectations for
further gradual removal of monetary policy
accommodation. Expectations for increases
in the supply of Treasury securities following
the federal budget agreement in early February
also appear to have contributed to the increase
in Treasury yields, while increased concerns
about trade policy both domestically and
abroad, political developments in Europe,
and the foreign economic outlook weighed on
longer-dated Treasury yields. Yields on 30-year
agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS)—an
important determinant of mortgage interest
13. The results of the Survey of Primary Dealers
and the Survey of Market Participants are available
on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website at
https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/primarydealer_
survey_questions.html and https://www.newyorkfed.org/
markets/survey_market_participants, respectively.
July 11, 2018
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
Percent
2020201920182017
31. Market-implied federal funds rate
Quarterly
Dec. 29, 2017
N
OTE
: The federal funds rate path is implied by quotes on overnight
index
swaps—a
derivative contract tied to the effective federal funds rate.
The
implied
path as of July 11, 2018, is compared with that as of December
29,
2017.
The path is estimated with a spline approach, assuming a term
premium
of 0 basis points. The paths extend through 2020:Q4.
S
OURCE: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.
2-year
30-year
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
32. Yields on nominal Treasury securities
Daily
10-year
N
OTE
: The Treasury ceased publication of the 30-year constant
maturity
series on February 18, 2002, and resumed that series on February 9, 2006.
SOURCE: Department of the Treasury.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 25
rates—increased about 60basis points over the
rst half of the year, a bit more than the rise in
the 10-year nominal Treasury yield, but remain
low by historical standards (gure33). Yields
on corporate debt securities—both investment
grade and high yield—rose more than Treasury
yields, leaving the spreads on corporate bond
yields over comparable-maturity Treasury
yields notably wider than at the beginning of
the year.
Broad equity indexes rose modestly amid
some bouts of market volatility
After surging as much as 20percent in 2017,
broad stock market indexes rose modestly,
on balance, so far this year amid some bouts
of heightened volatility in nancial markets
(gure34). The boost to equity prices from
rst-quarter earnings reports that generally
beat analysts’ expectations was reportedly
oset by increased uncertainty about trade
policy, rising interest rates, and concerns
about political developments abroad. While
stock prices for companies in the technology
and consumer discretionary sectors rose
notably, those of companies in the industrial
and nancial sectors declined modestly. After
spiking considerably in early February, the
implied volatility for the S&P 500 index—
the VIX—declined and ended the period
slightly above the low levels that prevailed in
2017. (For a discussion of nancial stability
issues, see the box “Developments Related to
Financial Stability.”)
Markets for Treasury securities, mortgage-
backed securities, and municipal bonds
have functioned well
On balance, indicators of Treasury market
functioning remained broadly stable over
the rst half of 2018. A variety of liquidity
metrics—including bid-ask spreads, bid sizes,
and estimates of transaction costs—have
displayed minimal signs of liquidity pressures
overall, with the exception of a brief period
of reduced liquidity in early February amid
elevated nancial market volatility. Liquidity
conditions in the agency MBS market were
S&P 500 index
25
50
75
100
125
150
175
200
December 31, 1999 = 100
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
34. Equity prices
Daily
Dow Jones bank index
S
OURCE
: Standard & Poor's Dow Jones Indices via Bloomberg. (For
Dow
Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
Yield
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
Basis points
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
33. Yield and spread on agency mortgage-backed securities
Percent
Spread
N
OTE
: The data are daily. Yield shown is for the Fannie Mae 30-year
current coupon, the coupon rate at which new mortgage-backed securities
would be priced at par, or face, value. Spread shown is to the average of the
5- and 10-year nominal Treasury yields. The data extend through July 11,
2018.
SOURCE
: Department of the Treasury; Barclays.
26 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
markets, commercial property valuations continue to
be stretched. Capitalization rates (computed as the ratio
of net operating income relative to property values)
remain low, and, in recent quarters, their spreads to
yields on 10-year Treasury securities have moved down
considerably. Finally, valuation pressures in residential
real estate markets increased modestly. Aggregate price-
to-rent ratios, adjusted for an estimate of their long-run
trend and the carrying cost of housing, are approaching
the cycle peaks of the early 1980s and early 1990s but
remain well below the levels observed on the eve of
the nancial crisis.
With households and businesses taken together, the
ratio of total debt to GDP is about in line with estimates
of its trend, although pockets of stress are evident. In
the household sector, the net expansion of household
debt has been in line with income growth and is
concentrated among prime-rated borrowers. However,
delinquency rates for some forms of consumer credit
have moved up, suggesting rising strains among riskier
borrowers even with unemployment very low. Banks
are reportedly tightening standards on credit card and
auto loans. In the nonnancial business sector, leverage
of corporate businesses remains high, as indicated by
a positive sectoral credit-to-GDP gap. Net issuance of
risky debt has risen in recent quarters, mainly driven by
the growth in leveraged loans (gure B). While current
The U.S. nancial system remains substantially more
resilient than during the decade before the nancial
crisis.
1
Valuations continue to be elevated for a range
of assets. In the private nonnancial sector, the ratio of
total debt to gross domestic product (GDP) is about in
line with an estimate of its trend, and vulnerabilities
associated with debt remain moderate on balance.
While borrowing among highly levered and lower-
rated rms is elevated and a future weakening in
economic activity could amplify some vulnerabilities
in the corporate sector, the ratio of household debt to
disposable income has remained stable in recent years.
Vulnerabilities associated with leverage in the nancial
sector appear low, reecting in part strong capital
positions of banks. However, some measures of hedge
fund leverage have increased. Vulnerabilities associated
with maturity and liquidity transformation continue to
be low compared with levels that generally prevailed
before 2008.
Valuation pressures in various asset markets
remain elevated by historical standards, although
they have declined somewhat since the start of the
year, as corporate bond prices have fallen and higher
earnings have helped rationalize equity prices. Market
movements were outsized in February, around the time
of the previous Monetary Policy Report. Since then,
volatility has receded, although it has ended up slightly
above the low levels seen in 2017. Even with higher
expected earnings due in part to changes in tax law, the
forward equity price-to-earnings ratio for the S&P 500
remains in the upper end of its historical distribution
(gure A). Treasury term premiums have increased
modestly from the beginning of the year but remain
low relative to historically observed values. Corporate
bond yields and their spreads to yields on comparable-
maturity Treasury securities have increased notably,
but they continue to be low by historical standards. In
particular, speculative-grade yields and spreads lie in
the bottom fth and bottom fourth of their respective
historical distributions. In leveraged loan markets,
issuance has been robust, spreads have reached their
lowest levels since the nancial crisis, and the presence
of loan covenants has decreased further. In real estate
1. An overview of the framework for assessing nancial
stability in the United States is provided in Lael Brainard
(2018), “An Update on the Federal Reserve’s Financial Stability
Agenda,” speech delivered at the Center for Global Economy
and Business, Stern School of Business, New York University,
New York, April3, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/
speech/brainard20180403a.htm.
Developments Related to Financial Stability
5
10
15
20
25
30
Ratio
201820142010200620021998199419901986
A. Forward price-to-earnings ratio of S&P 500 firms
Monthly
Historical median
N
OTE: The data depict the aggregate forward price-to-earnings ratio
of
S&P
500 firms. The historical median is based on data from 1985 to
the
present.
Shaded bars indicate periods of recession as defined by the
National
Bureau
of Economic Research. Data are based on 12-month-ahead
expected
earnings per share.
S
OURCE
: Staff estimates based on Thomson Reuters, IBES.
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 27
a severe global recession.
2
The hypothetical “severely
adverse” scenario—the most stringent scenario
yet used in the Board’s stress tests, with the U.S.
unemployment rate rising almost 6percentage points to
10percent—projects $578billion in total losses for the
35 participating banks during the nine quarters tested.
Since 2009, these rms have added about $800billion
in common equity capital. The Board also evaluates the
capital planning processes of the participating banks,
including the rms’ planned capital actions, such as
dividend payments and share buybacks.
3
The Board did
not object to the capital plans of 34 rms.Although
the recent U.S. tax legislation is expected to increase
banks’ post-tax earnings, and hence their ability
to accrete capital, it did lead to one-time losses,
decreasing banks’ capital ratios at the end of 2017, the
jumping-off point of the stress tests. In part because
of these effects, evident in text gure36, two rms
were required to maintain their capital distributions
at the levels they paid in recent years. Separately, one
rm will be required to address the management and
analysis of its counterparty exposure under stress. The
Board objected to the capital plan of one bank because
of qualitative concerns.
Vulnerabilities associated with liquidity and
maturity transformation—that is, the nancing of
illiquid assets or long-maturity assets with short-
maturity debt—continue to be low, owing in part to
liquidity regulations for banks and money market
reform. Large banks have strong liquidity positions,
because their use of core deposits as a source of
funding and their holdings of high-quality liquid
assets remain near historical highs, while their use of
short-term wholesale funding as a share of liabilities
is near historical lows. Since the money market fund
reforms implemented in October2016, assets under
management at prime funds, institutions that proved
vulnerable to runs in the past, have remained far below
pre-reform levels. In addition, the growth in alternative
short-term investment vehicles, which may have some
corporate credit conditions are favorable overall,
with low interest expenses and defaults, the elevated
leverage in this sector could result in higher future
default rates. In addition, weak protection from loan
covenants could reduce early intervention by lenders
and lower recovery rates for investors on default.
Investors may also be exposed to signicant repricing
risks because bond yields and credit risk premiums are
both low.
Vulnerabilities from nancial-sector leverage
continue to be relatively low. Core nancial
intermediaries, including large banks, insurance
companies, and broker-dealers, appear well positioned
to weather economic stress. Regulatory capital ratios for
the global systemically important banks have remained
well above the fully phased-in enhanced regulatory
requirements and are close to historical highs. Capital
levels at insurance companies and broker-dealers
also remain relatively robust by historical standards.
However, some indicators of hedge fund leverage in
the equity market, such as the provision of total margin
credit to equity investors, have risen to historically
elevated levels, and in the past few quarters dealers
have reportedly eased, on net, price terms to their
hedge fund clients.
The results of supervisory stress tests released in June
by the Federal Reserve Board conrm that the nation’s
largest banks are strongly capitalized and would be
able to lend to households and businesses even during
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
60
80
Billions of dollars
2018201620142012201020082006
B. Total net issuance of risky debt
Quarterly
NOTE: Data are 4-quarter moving averages and extend through
2018:Q2.
Total
net issuance of risky debt is the sum of the net issuance
of
speculative-grade and unrated bonds and leveraged loans.
SOURCE
: Mergent Fixed Investment Securities Database, S&P
Leveraged
Commentary & Data.
2. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(2018), “Federal Reserve Board Releases Results of Supervisory
Bank Stress Tests,” press release, June21, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
bcreg20180621a.htm.
3. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(2018), “Federal Reserve Releases Results of Comprehensive
Capital Analysis and Review (CCAR),” press release, June29,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
bcreg20160629a.htm.
(continued on next page)
28 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
4. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(2016), “Regulatory Capital Rules: The Federal Reserve Board’s
Framework for Implementing the U.S. Basel III Countercyclical
Capital Buffer,” nal policy statement (Docket No. R-1529),
Federal Register, vol. 81 (September16), pp. 63682–88.
similar vulnerabilities, continues to be limited, as
investors have shifted primarily from prime funds into
government funds.
Risks from abroad are moderate overall. Advanced
foreign economies (AFEs), many of which have
signicant nancial and real linkages to the United
States, continue to have notable or elevated valuations
in some asset markets and, in a few countries, high
levels of household debt relative to GDP. These
factors have contributed to some AFEs announcing
or implementing macroprudential actions, including
increases in countercyclical capital buffers, over the
past couple of years. More generally, AFE nancial
sectors continue their slow pace of deleveraging
that started after the global nancial and euro-area
sovereign debt crises. In addition, low corporate debt
spreads in the past few years have yet to translate
into any marked increase in leverage in most of these
countries’ nonnancial corporate sectors. Some major
emerging market economies continue to harbor
more pronounced vulnerabilities, reecting some
combination of the following: substantial corporate
leverage, scal concerns, or excessive reliance on
foreign funding. Globally, potential downside risks to
international nancial markets and nancial stability
include political uncertainty, an intensication of trade
tensions, and challenges posed by rising interest rates.
The countercyclical capital buffer (CCyB) is a
macroprudential tool the Federal Reserve Board can
use to increase the resilience of the nancial system
by raising capital requirements on the largest banks.
Activating the CCyB is appropriate when systemic
vulnerabilities are meaningfully above normal.
4
The
Board is closely monitoring the level and conguration
of systemic vulnerabilities described earlier.
Financial Stability (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 29
also generally stable. Overall, the functioning
of Treasury and agency MBS markets has not
been materially aected by the implementation
of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
normalization program, including the
accompanying reduction in reinvestment of
principal payments from the Federal Reserve’s
securities holdings. Credit conditions in
municipal bond markets have remained stable
since the turn of the year. Over that period,
yield spreads on 20-year general obligation
municipal bonds over comparable-maturity
Treasury securities edged up a bit.
Money market rates have moved up in
line with increases in the FOMC’s target
range
Conditions in domestic short-term funding
markets have also remained generally stable
so far in 2018. Yields on a broad set of money
market instruments moved higher in response
to the FOMC’s policy actions in March and
June. Some money market rates rose during
the rst quarter more than what would
normally occur with monetary tightening.
For example, the spreads of certicates of
deposit and term London interbank oered
rates relative to overnight index swap (OIS)
rates increased notably, reportedly reecting
increased issuance of Treasury bills and
perhaps also the anticipated tax-induced
repatriation of foreign earnings by U.S.
corporations. The upward pressure on short-
term funding rates, beyond that driven by
expected monetary policy, eased in recent
months, leading to a narrowing of spreads
of some money market rates to OIS rates.
However, the spreads remain wider than at the
beginning of the year.
Bank credit continued to expand and
bank protability improved
Aggregate credit provided by commercial
banks continued to increase through the rst
quarter of 2018 at a pace similar to the one
seen in 2017. Its pace was slower than that of
nominal GDP, thus leaving the ratio of total
commercial bank credit to current-dollar
30 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
GDP slightly lower than in the previous year
(gure35). Available data for the second
quarter suggest that growth in banks’ core
loans continued to be moderate. Measures of
bank protability improved in the rst quarter
of 2018 after having experienced a temporary
decline in the last quarter of 2017. Weaker
fourth-quarter measures of bank protability
were partly driven by higher write-downs of
deferred tax assets in response to the U.S. tax
legislation (gure36).
International Developments
Political developments and signs of
moderating growth weighed on advanced
foreign economy asset prices
Since February, political developments
in Europe and moderation in economic
growth outside of the United States weighed
on some risky asset prices in advanced
foreign economies (AFEs). Interest rates on
sovereign bonds in several countries in the
European periphery rose notably relative to
core countries, and European bank shares
came under pressure, as investors focused
on the formation of the Italian government.
Nonetheless, peripheral bond spreads
remained well below their levels at the height
of the euro-area crisis, and the moves partly
retraced as a government was put in place.
Broad stock price indexes were little changed
on net (gure37). In contrast to the United
States, long-term sovereign yields and market-
implied paths of policy rates in the core euro
area as well as the United Kingdom declined
somewhat, and rates were little changed in
Japan (gure38).
Heightened investor focus on
vulnerabilities in emerging market
economies led asset prices to come under
pressure
Investor concerns about nancial
vulnerabilities in several emerging market
economies (EMEs) intensied this spring
against the backdrop of rising U.S. interest
rates. Broad measures of EME sovereign
United Kingdom
Euro area
80
90
100
110
120
130
140
Week ending January 7, 2015 = 100
2018201720162015
37. Equity indexes for selected foreign economies
Weekly
Emerging market economies
N
OTE
: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend
through
July 11, 2018.
S
OURCE: For euro area, DJ Euro Stoxx Index; for United Kingdom,
FTSE
100
Stock Index; for emerging market economies, MSCI Emerging
Markets
Local Currency Index; all via Bloomberg.
Return on assets
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent, annual rate
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
36. Profitability of bank holding companies
Percent, annual rate
Return on equity
N
OTE
: The data are quarterly and are seasonally adjusted.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-9C, Consolidated
Financial
Statements for Bank Holding Companies.
55
60
65
70
75
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
35. Ratio of total commercial bank credit to nominal gross
domestic product
Quarterly
SOURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.8, “Assets
and
Liabilities
of Commercial Banks in the United States”; Bureau of
Economic
Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 31
bond spreads over U.S. Treasury yields
widened notably, and benchmark EME equity
indexes declined, as investors scrutinized
macroeconomic policy approaches in several
countries. Turkey and Argentina, which faced
persistently high ination, expansionary scal
policies, and large current account decits,
were among the worst performers. Trade
policy developments between the United
States and its trading partners also weighed on
EME asset prices, especially on stock prices
in China and some emerging Asian countries.
EME mutual funds saw net outows in May
and June after generally solid inows earlier
in the year (gure39). While movements in
asset prices and capital ows were notable for
a number of economies, broad indicators of
nancial stress in EMEs remained low relative
to levels seen during other periods of stress in
recent years.
The dollar appreciated
After depreciating during 2017, the broad
exchange value of the U.S. dollar has
appreciated moderately in recent months
(gure40). Factors contributing to the
appreciation of the dollar likely include
moderating growth in some foreign economies
combined with continued output strength
and ongoing policy tightening in the United
States, downside risks stemming from political
developments in Europe and several EMEs,
and the recent developments in trade policy.
Several currencies appeared particularly
sensitive to trade policy developments,
including the Canadian dollar and the
Mexican peso, related to the North American
Free Trade Agreement negotiations, as well
as the Chinese renminbi, which fell notably
against the dollar in June.
The pace of economic activity moderated
in the AFEs
In the rst quarter, real GDP growth
decelerated in all major AFEs and turned
negative in Japan, down from robust rates of
activity in 2017 (gure41). Part of this slowing
is a result of temporary factors, though,
EMBI+ (left axis)
60
40
20
+
_
0
20
40
60
Billions of dollars
200
250
300
350
400
450
500
2018201720162015
39. Emerging market mutual fund flows and spreads
Basis points
Apr.
June
N
OTE
: The bond and equity fund flow data are quarterly sums of
weekly
data from January 1, 2015, to March 31, 2018, and monthly sums of
weekly
data from April 1, 2018, to June 30, 2018. The fund flows data exclude funds
located in China. The J.P. Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index
Plus
(EMBI+) data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through July
4,
2018.
S
OURCE
: For bond and equity fund flows, EPFR Global; for EMBI+,
J.P.
Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Index Plus via Bloomberg.
Bond fund flows (right axis)
Equity fund flows (right axis)
United Kingdom
Japan
Germany
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
Percent
2015 2016 2017 2018
38. Nominal 10-year government bond yields in
selected advanced economies
Weekly
United States
N
OTE: The data are weekly averages of daily benchmark yields and
extend
through July 11, 2018.
S
OURCE
:Bloomberg.
32 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
including unusually cold weather in Japan
and the United Kingdom, labor strikes in the
euro area, and disruptions in oil production in
Canada. In most AFEs, economic indicators
for the second quarter, including purchasing
manager surveys and exports, are generally
consistent with solid economic growth.
Despite tight labor markets,
ination pressures remain subdued in
most AFEs . . .
Sustained increases in oil prices provided
upward pressure on consumer price ination
across all AFEs in the rst half of the year
(gure42). However, core ination has
generally remained muted in most AFEs,
despite further improvement in labor market
conditions. In Canada, in contrast, core
ination picked up amid solid wage growth,
pushing the total ination rate above the
central bank target.
. . . prompting central banks to maintain
highly accommodative monetary policies
With underlying ination still subdued, the
Bank of Japan and the European Central
Bank (ECB) kept their policy rates at
historically low levels, although the ECB
indicated it would again reduce the pace of
its asset purchases starting in October. The
Bank of England and the Bank of Canada,
which both began raising interest rates last
year, signaled that further rate increases will
be gradual, given a moderation in the pace of
economic activity.
In emerging Asia, growth remained
solid . . .
Economic growth in China remained solid
in the rst quarter of 2018, as a rebound in
steel production and strong external demand
bolstered a recovery in industrial activity
and overall growth (gure43). Indicators
of investment and retail sales have slowed
in recent months, however, suggesting that
the authorities’ eort to rein in credit may
have softened domestic demand. Most other
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent, annual rate
20182017201620152014
41. Real gross domestic product growth in selected
advanced foreign economies
Q1
S
OURCE:
For the United Kingdom, Office for National Statistics; for Japan,
Cabinet Office, Government of Japan; for the euro area, Eurostat; for
Canada,
Statistics Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
United Kingdom
Japan
Euro area
Canada
British pound
Mexican peso
Euro
90
100
110
120
130
140
150
Week ending January 7, 2015 = 100
2018201720162015
40. U.S. dollar exchange rate indexes
Weekly
Dollar appreciation
Broad dollar
N
OTE
: The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly
averages of daily data and extend through July 11, 2018. As indicated by
the
arrow, increases in the data represent U.S. dollar appreciation, and
decreases
represent U.S. dollar depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.10,
“Foreign
Exchange Rates.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 33
emerging Asian economies registered strong
growth in the rst quarter of 2018, partly
reecting solid external demand.
. . . while growth in some Latin American
economies was mixed
In Mexico, real GDP surged in the rst quarter
as economic activity rebounded from two
major earthquakes and a hurricane last year.
Following a brief recovery in the rst half of
2017, Brazil’s economy stalled in the fourth
quarter and grew tepidly in the rst quarter,
and a truckers’ strike paralyzed economic
activity in late May.
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
12
Percent, annual rate
20182017201620152014
43. Real gross domestic product growth in selected
emerging market economies
Q1
N
OTE
: The data for China are seasonally adjusted by Board staff. The data
for
Korea, Mexico, and Brazil are seasonally adjusted by their respective
government agencies.
SOURCE
: For China, China National Bureau of Statistics; for Korea, Bank
of
Korea; for Mexico, Instituto Nacional de Estadistica y Geografia; for
Brazil, Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatistica; all via Haver Analytics.
China
Korea
Mexico
Brazil
United Kingdom
Japan
Euro area
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
12-month percent change
2018201720162015
42. Consumer price inflation in selected advanced foreign
economies
Monthly
Canada
N
OTE
: The data for the euro area incorporate the flash estimate for
June
2018. The data for Canada, Japan, and the United Kingdom extend
through
May 2018.
S
OURCE
:
For the United Kingdom, Office for National Statistics; for Japan,
Ministry of International Affairs and Communications; for the euro
area,
Statistical Office of the European Communities; for Canada,
Statistics
Canada; all via Haver Analytics.
35
The Federal Open Market Committee
continued to gradually increase the
federal funds target range in the rst half
of the year . . .
Since December2015, the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) has been
gradually increasing its target range for
the federal funds rate as the economy has
continued to make progress toward the
Committee’s congressionally mandated
objectives of maximum employment and
price stability. In the rst half of this year, the
Committee continued this gradual process of
scaling back monetary policy accommodation,
increasing its target range for the federal funds
rate ¼percentage point at its meetings in both
March and June. With these increases, the
federal funds rate is currently in the range of
1¾ to 2percent (gure44).
14
The Committee’s
decisions reected the continued strengthening
14. See Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System (2018), “Federal Reserve Issues
FOMC Statement,” press release, March21, https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20180321a.htm; and Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System (2018), “Federal Reserve
Issues FOMC Statement,” press release, June13, https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20180613a.htm.
of the labor market and the accumulating
evidence that, after many years of running
below the Committee’s 2percent longer-
run objective, ination had moved close to
2percent.
. . . but monetary policy continues to
support economic growth
Even after the gradual increases in the federal
funds rate over the rst half of the year, the
Committee judges that the stance of monetary
policy remains accommodative, thereby
supporting strong labor market conditions
and a sustained return to 2percent ination.
In particular, the federal funds rate remains
somewhat below most FOMC participants’
estimates of its longer-run value.
The Committee expects that a gradual
approach to increasing the target range for
the federal funds rate will be consistent with
a sustained expansion of economic activity,
strong labor market conditions, and ination
near the Committee’s symmetric 2percent
objective over the medium term. Consistent
with this outlook, in the most recent
Summary of Economic Projections (SEP),
which was compiled at the time of the June
FOMC meeting, the median of participants’
Part 2
monetary PoLicy
Target federal funds rate
2-year Treasury rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
44. Selected interest rates
Daily
10-year Treasury rate
N
OTE
: The 2-year and 10-year Treasury rates are the constant-maturity yields based on the most actively traded securities.
SOURCE
: Department of the Treasury; Federal Reserve Board.
36 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
assessments for the appropriate level of the
target range for the federal funds rate at
year-end rises gradually over the period from
2018 to 2020 and stands somewhat above the
median projection for its longer-run level by
the end of 2019 and through 2020.
15
Future changes in the federal funds rate
will depend on the economic outlook as
informed by incoming data
The FOMC has continued to emphasize
that, in determining the timing and size of
future adjustments to the target range for
the federal funds rate, it will assess realized
and expected economic conditions relative
to its maximum-employment objective and
its symmetric 2percent ination objective.
This assessment will take into account a wide
range of information, including measures
of labor market conditions, indicators of
ination pressures and ination expectations,
and readings on nancial and international
developments.
In evaluating the stance of monetary policy,
policymakers routinely consult prescriptions
from a variety of policy rules, which can serve
15. See the June SEP, which appeared as an addendum
to the minutes of the June12–13, 2018, meeting of the
FOMC and is presented in Part 3 of thisreport.
as useful benchmarks. However, the use and
interpretation of such prescriptions require,
among other considerations, careful judgments
about the choice and measurement of the
inputs to these rules such as estimates of the
neutral interest rate, which are highly uncertain
(see the box “Complexities of Monetary
PolicyRules”).
The FOMC has continued to implement
its program to gradually reduce the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
The Committee has continued to implement
the balance sheet normalization program
described in the June2017 Addendum to the
Policy Normalization Principles and Plans.
16
This program is gradually and predictably
reducing the Federal Reserve’s securities
holdings by decreasing the reinvestment of the
principal payments it receives from securities
held in the System Open Market Account.
Since the initiation of the balance sheet
normalization program in October of last year,
such payments have been reinvested to the
extent that they exceeded gradually rising caps
(gure45).
16. The addendum, adopted on June13, 2017, is
available at https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
files/FOMC_PolicyNormalization.20170613.pdf.
45. Principal payments on SOMA securities
N: Reinvestment and redemption amounts of agency mortgage-backed securities are projections starting in June 2018. The data
extend through December 2019.
S: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities Treasury securities
Billions of dollarsMonthly
Billions of dollarsMonthly
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
201920182017
Monthly cap
Redemptions
Reinvestments
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
201920182017
Monthly cap
Redemptions
Reinvestments
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 37
(continued on next page)
reect the three key principles of good monetary policy
noted earlier. Each rule takes into account estimates
of how far the economy is from achieving the Federal
Reserve’s dual-mandate goals of maximum employment
and price stability.
Four of the ve rules include the difference
between the rate of unemployment that is sustainable
in the longer run and the current unemployment
rate (the unemployment rate gap); the rst-difference
rule includes the change in the unemployment gap
rather than its level.
3
In addition, four of the ve rules
include the difference between recent ination and the
FOMC’s longer-run objective (2percent as measured
by the annual change in the price index for personal
consumption expenditures, or PCE), while the price-
level rule includes the gap between the level of prices
today and the level of prices that would be observed
if ination had been constant at 2percent from a
specied starting year (PLgap
t
).
4
The price-level rule
thereby takes account of the deviation of ination from
Overview
Monetary policy rules are mathematical formulas
that relate a policy interest rate, such as the federal
funds rate, to a small number of other economic
variables—typically including the deviation of ination
from its target value along with an estimate of resource
slack in the economy. Policy rules can provide helpful
guidance for policymakers. Indeed, since 2004,
prescriptions from policy rules have been included
in written materials that are routinely sent to the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). However,
interpretation of the prescriptions of policy rules
requires careful judgment about the measurement of
the inputs to the rules and the implications of the many
considerations that the rules do not take into account.
Policy rules can incorporate key principles of good
monetary policy.
1
One key principle is that monetary
policy should respond in a predictable way to changes
in economic conditions. A second key principle is
that monetary policy should be accommodative when
ination is below the desired level and employment
is below its maximum sustainable level; conversely,
monetary policy should be restrictive when the
opposite holds. A third key principle is that, to stabilize
ination, the policy rate should be adjusted by more
than one-for-one in response to persistent increases or
decreases in ination.
Economists have analyzed many monetary policy
rules, including the well-known Taylor (1993) rule.
Other rules include the “balanced approach” rule, the
“adjusted Taylor (1993)” rule, the “price level” rule, and
the “rst difference” rule (gure A).
2
These policy rules
Complexities of Monetary Policy Rules
1. For discussion regarding principles for the conduct of
monetary policy and monetary policy rules, see Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2018), “Monetary
Policy Principles and Practice,” Board of Governors, https://
www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/monetary-policy-
principles-and-practice.htm.
2. The Taylor (1993) rule was suggested in John B. Taylor
(1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,Carnegie-
Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol.39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp.319–41. The
adjusted Taylor (1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-Ination Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. A price-level rule
was discussed in Robert E. Hall (1984), “Monetary Strategy
with an Elastic Price Standard,” in Price Stability and Public
Policy, proceedings of a symposium sponsored by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyo.,
August2–3 (Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City), pp. 137–59, https://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/
sympos/1984/s84.pdf. Finally, the rst-difference rule was
introduced by Athanasios Orphanides (2003), “Historical
Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,Journal
of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983–1022. A
comprehensive review of policy rules is in John B. Taylor
and John C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust Rules for
Monetary Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and Michael
Woodford, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol.3B
(Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same volume
of the Handbook of Monetary Economics also discusses
approaches other than policy rules for deriving policy rate
prescriptions.
3. The Taylor (1993) rule represented slack in resource
utilization using an output gap (the difference between the
current level of real gross domestic product (GDP) and what
GDP would be if the economy was operating at maximum
employment). The rules in gure A represent slack in resource
utilization using the unemployment gap instead, because that
gap better captures the FOMC’s statutory goal to promote
maximum employment. Movements in these alternative
measures of resource utilization are highly correlated. For
more information, see the note below gure A.
4. Calculating the prescriptions of the price-level rule
requires selecting a starting year for the price level from which
to cumulate the 2percent annual ination. Figure B uses 1998
as the starting year. Around that time, the underlying trend
of ination and longer-term ination expectations stabilized
at a level consistent with PCE price ination being close to
2percent.
38 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
also recognizes that the federal funds rate cannot be
reduced materially below zero. If ination runs below
the 2percent objective during periods when the rule
prescribes setting the federal funds rate well below
zero, the price-level rule will, over time, provide
accommodation to make up for the past ination
shortfall.
The U.S. economy is complex, and the monetary
policy rules shown in gure A do not capture many
elements that are relevant to the conduct of monetary
policy. Moreover, as shown in gure B, different
monetary policy rules often offer quite different
prescriptions for the federal funds rate.
5
In practice,
there is no unique criterion for favoring one rule over
another. In recent years, almost all of the policy rules
the long-run objective in earlier periods as well as
the current period. Thus, if ination had been running
persistently above 2percent, the price-level rule would
prescribe a higher level for the federal funds rate than
rules that use the current ination gap. Likewise,
if ination had been running persistently below
2percent, the price-level rule would prescribe setting
the policy rate lower than rules that use the current
ination gap.
The adjusted Taylor (1993) rule recognizes that
the federal funds rate cannot be reduced materially
below zero, and that following the prescriptions
of the standard Taylor (1993) rule after a recession
during which interest rates have fallen to their lower
bound may, for a time, not provide enough policy
accommodation. To make up for the cumulative
shortfall in accommodation (Z
t
), the adjusted rule
prescribes only a gradual return of the policy rate to
the (positive) levels prescribed by the standard Taylor
(1993) rule after the economy begins to recover.
The particular price-level rule specied in gure A
Taylor (1993) rule
93
= + +0.5
(
)
+(
)
= + +0.5
(
)
+2(
)
Taylor (1993) rule, adjusted
93
= {
93
, 0}
= { + +
(
)
+0.5
( ), 0}
=
−1
+0.5
(
)
+
(
)
−(
−4
−4
)
Balanced-approach rule
Price-level rule
First-dierence rule
N: R
t
T93
, R
t
BA
, R
t
T93adj
, R
t
PL
, and R
t
FD
represent the values of the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by the Taylor (1993),
R
t
denotes the actual nominal federal funds rate for quarter t, π
t
is four-quarter price ination for quarter t, u
t
is the
t, and r
t
LR
is the level of the neutral real federal funds rate in the longer run that, on average, is
LR
. In addition, u
t
LR
is the rate of unemployment in the longer run. Z
t
is the cumulative sum of past deviations of the federal
.
t
is the percent deviation of the actual level of prices from a price level that rises 2 percent per year from its level in a
The Taylor (1993) rule and other policy rules are generally written in terms of the deviation of real output from its full
5. These prescriptions are calculated using (1) published
data for ination and the unemployment rate and (2)
survey-based estimates of the longer-run value of the
neutral real interest rate and the longer-run value of the
unemploymentrate.
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 39
(continued on next page)
growth, changing demographics, and other shifts in the
structure of the economy. As a result, estimates of the
neutral real interest rate in the longer run made today
may differ substantially from estimates made later.
Academic studies have estimated the longer-
run value of the neutral real interest rate using
statistical techniques to capture the variations among
ination, interest rates, real gross domestic product,
unemployment, and other data series. The range of
estimates is wide but suggests that the neutral real rate
has declined since the turn of the century (gure C).
7
There is substantial statistical uncertainty surrounding
each estimate of the longer-run value of the neutral
real rate, as evidenced by the width of the 95percent
shown have called for rising values of the federal funds
rate, but the pace of tightening that the rules prescribe
has varied widely.
Uncertainty about the neutral interest rate
in the longer run
The Taylor (1993), balanced-approach, adjusted
Taylor (1993), and price-level rules provide
prescriptions for the level of the federal funds rate;
all require an estimate of the neutral real interest rate
in the longer run (r
t
LR
)—that is, the level of the real
federal funds rate that is expected to be consistent, in
the longer run, with maximum employment and stable
ination.
6
The neutral real interest rate in the longer
run is determined by structural features of the economy
and is not observable. In addition, its value may vary
over time because of uctuations in trend productivity
First-difference rule
Price-level ruleTarget federal funds rate
Balanced-approach rule
Taylor (1993) rule, adjusted
8
6
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent
2018201620142012201020082006200420022000
Quarterly
Taylor (1993) rule
N
OTE: The rules use historical values of inflation, the federal funds rate, and the unemployment rate. Inflation is measured as the 4-quarter percent change
price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) excluding food and energy. Quarterly projections of long-run values for the federal funds rate
unemployment rate are derived through interpolations of biannual projections from Blue Chip Economic Indicators. The long-run value for inflation is
2 percent. The target value of the price level is the average level of the price index for PCE excluding food and energy in 1998 extrapolated at 2 percent
6. The rst-difference rule shown in gure A does not
require an estimate of the neutral real interest rate in the
longer run. However, this rule has its own shortcomings. For
example, research suggests that this sort of rule will result in
greater volatility in employment and ination relative to what
would be obtained under the Taylor (1993) and balanced-
approach rules unless the estimates of the neutral real federal
funds rate in the longer run and the rate of unemployment in
the longer run that are included in those rules are sufciently
far from their true values.
7. The range of estimates is computed using published
values or values computed using the methodology from the
following studies: Marco Del Negro, Domenico Giannone,
Marc P. Giannoni, and Andrea Tambalotti (2017), “Safety,
Liquidity, and the Natural Rate of Interest,Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 235–94, https://
www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2017/08/
delnegrotextsp17bpea.pdf; Kathryn Holston, Thomas Laubach,
and John C. Williams (2017), “Measuring the Natural
Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants,
Journal of International Economics, supp. 1, vol. 108
(May), pp.S59–75; Benjamin K. Johannsen and Elmar
Mertens (2016), “The Expected Real Interest Rate in the
Long Run: Time Series Evidence with the Effective Lower
Bound,” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of Governors
40 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
uncertainty bands for the estimated values in the rst
quarter of 2018 (gure D).
The longer-run normal level of the federal funds
rate under appropriate monetary policy—equal to
the sum of the neutral real interest rate in the longer
run and the FOMC’s 2percent ination objective—is
one benchmark for evaluating the current stance
of monetary policy. Uncertainty about the longer-
run value of the neutral real interest rate leads to
uncertainty about how far the current federal funds
rate is from its longer-run normal level. For the Taylor
(1993), balanced-approach, adjusted Taylor (1993), and
price-level rules, different estimates of the neutral real
interest rate in the longer run translate one-for-one to
differences in the prescribed setting of the federal funds
rate. As a result, the substantial statistical uncertainty
accompanying estimates of the neutral rate in the
longer run implies substantial uncertainty surrounding
the prescriptions of each policy rule. Following the
prescriptions of a policy rule with an incorrect value of
the neutral rate could lead to poor economic outcomes.
If the longer-run value of the neutral real interest rate
is currently at the low end of the range of estimates,
of the Federal Reserve System, February9), https://www.
federalreserve.gov/econresdata/notes/feds-notes/2016/
the-expected-real-interest-rate-in-the-long-run-time-series-
evidence-with-the-effective-lower-bound-20160209.html;
Michael T. Kiley (2015), “What Can the Data Tell Us about
the Equilibrium Real Interest Rate?” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2015-77 (Washington: Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System, September), http://dx.doi.
org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.077; Thomas Laubach and John
C. Williams (2015), “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest
Redux,” Hutchins Center Working Paper 15 (Washington:
Brookings Institution, November), https://www.brookings.
edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/07/WP15-Laubach-Williams-
natural-interest-rate-redux.pdf; Kurt F. Lewis and Francisco
Vazquez-Grande (2017), “Measuring the Natural Rate of
Interest: Alternative Specications,” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2017-059 (Washington: Board of
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2018201520122009200620032000
C. Range of selected estimates for the neutral real federal
funds rate in the longer run
Quarterly
NOTE: The shaded bars indicate periods of business recession as defined
by
the National Bureau of Economic Research.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board staff calculations, along with
references
listed in box note 7.
Range of selected estimates
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
then monetary policy is more likely to be constrained
by the lower bound on nominal interest rates in the
future. Historically, the FOMC has cut the federal
funds rate by 5percentage points, on average, during
downturns in the economy. Cutting the federal funds
rate by this much in response to a future economic
downturn may not be feasible if the neutral federal
funds rate is as low as most of the estimates suggest.
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June), https://
doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.059; Thomas A. Lubik and
Christian Matthes (2015), “Calculating the Natural Rate of
Interest: A Comparison of Two Alternative Approaches,”
Economic Brief 15-10 (Richmond, Va.: Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond, October), https://www.richmondfed.org/-/media/
richmondfedorg/publications/research/economic_brief/2015/
pdf/eb_15-10.pdf.
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 41
D. Point estimates and uncertainty bands for neutral real rate in the longer run as of 2018:Q1
Study Point estimate
95percent uncertainty band
Del Negro and others (2017)
1.3 (.7, 2.1)
Holston and others (2017) .6
(-2.5, 3.7)
Johannsen and Mertens (2016) .7 (-1.3, 2.5)
Kiley (2015) .4 (-.6, 1.6)
Laubach and Williams (2015) .1 (-5.4, 5.6)
Lewis and Vazquez-Grande (2017) 1.8 (.5, 3.1)
Lubik and Matthes (2015) 1.0 (-2.3, 4.5)
S: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations, along with references listed in box note7.
As a result, it may not be feasible to provide the levels
of accommodation prescribed by many policy rules,
potentially leading to elevated unemployment and
ination averaging below the Committee’s 2percent
objective.
8
Rules that try to offset the cumulative
shortfall of accommodation posed by the lower bound
on nominal interest rates, such as the adjusted Taylor
(1993) rule, or make up the cumulative shortfall in
the level of prices, such as the price-level rule, are
intended to mitigate the effects of the lower bound
on the economy by providing more accommodation
than prescribed by rules that do not have these
makeupfeatures.
9
In the years following the nancial crisis, with the
federal funds rate close to zero, the FOMC recognized
that it would have limited scope to respond to an
unexpected weakening in the economy by lowering
short-term interest rates. This risk has, in recent years,
provided a sound rationale for following a more
gradual path of rate increases than that prescribed by
some policy rules. In these circumstances, increasing
the policy rate quickly in order to have room to
cut rates during an economic downturn could be
counterproductive because it might make a downturn
more likely to happen.
8. For further discussion of these issues, see Michael T.
Kiley and John M. Roberts (2017), “Monetary Policy in a Low
Interest Rate World,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Spring, pp. 317–72, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/
uploads/2017/08/kileytextsp17bpea.pdf.
9. Economists have found that a “makeup” policy can
be the best response in theory when the policy interest
rate is constrained at zero. See Ben S. Bernanke (2017),
“Monetary Policy in a New Era,” paper presented at
“Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy,” a conference held at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington,
October12–13, https://piie.com/system/les/documents/
bernanke20171012paper.pdf; and Michael Woodford (1999),
“Commentary: How Should Monetary Policy Be Conducted
in an Era of Price Stability?” in New Challenges for Monetary
Policy, proceedings of a symposium sponsored by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City (Kansas City, Mo.: Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City) pp. 277–316, https://www.
kansascityfed.org/publications/research/escp/symposiums/
escp-1999.
42 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
In the rst quarter, the Open Market Desk
at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
as directed by the Committee, reinvested
principal payments from the Federal Reserve’s
holdings of Treasury securities maturing
during each calendar month in excess of
$12billion. The Desk also reinvested in agency
mortgage-backed securities (MBS) the amount
of principal payments from the Federal
Reserve’s holdings of agency debt and agency
MBS received during each calendar month in
excess of $8billion. Over the second quarter,
payments of principal from maturing Treasury
securities and from the Federal Reserve’s
holdings of agency debt and agency MBS were
reinvested to the extent that they exceeded
$18billion and $12billion, respectively. At
its meeting in June, the FOMC increased the
cap for Treasury securities to $24billion and
the cap for agency debt and agency MBS
to $16billion, both eective in July. The
Committee has indicated that the caps for
Treasury securities and for agency securities
will increase to $30billion and $20billion per
month, respectively, in October. These terminal
caps will remain in place until the Committee
judges that the Federal Reserve is holding no
more securities than necessary to implement
monetary policy eciently and eectively.
The implementation of the program has
proceeded smoothly without causing disruptive
price movements in Treasury and MBS
markets. As the caps have increased gradually
and predictably, the Federal Reserve’s total
assets have started to decrease, from about
$4.4trillion last October to about $4.3trillion
at present, with holdings of Treasury securities
at approximately $2.4trillion and holdings
of agency and agency MBS at approximately
$1.7trillion (gure46).
The Federal Reserve’s implementation of
monetary policy has continued smoothly
To implement the FOMC’s decisions to raise
the target range for the federal funds rate in
March and June of 2018, the Federal Reserve
increased the rate of interest on excess reserves
(IOER) along with the interest rate oered
on overnight reverse repurchase agreements
(ON RRPs). Specically, the Federal Reserve
increased the IOER rate to 1¾percent and
the ON RRP oering rate to 1½percent in
March. In June, the Federal Reserve increased
the IOER rate to 1.95percent—5 basis points
below the top of the target range—and the
ON RRP oering rate to 1¾percent. In
addition, the Board of Governors approved
Trillions of dollars
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
46. Federal Reserve assets and liabilities
Weekly
Assets
Liabilities and capital
Other assets
Credit and liquidity
facilities
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings
Treasury securities held outright
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Deposits of depository institutions
Capital and other liabilities
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
N
OTE: “Credit and liquidity facilities” consists of primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; term auction credit; central bank liquidity swaps; support
for
Maiden Lane, Bear Stearns, and AIG; and other credit facilities, including the Primary Dealer Credit Facility, the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper
Money
Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper Funding Facility, and the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility. “Other
assets”
includes unamortized premiums and discounts on securities held outright. “Capital and other liabilities” includes reverse repurchase agreements, the
U.S.
Treasury General Account, and the U.S. Treasury Supplementary Financing Account. The data extend through July 4, 2018.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Affecting Reserve Balances.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 43
a ¼percentage point increase in the discount
rate (the primary credit rate) in both March
and June. Yields on a broad set of money
market instruments moved higher, roughly in
line with the federal funds rate, in response
to the FOMC’s policy decisions in March
and June. Usage of the ON RRP facility
has declined, on net, since the turn of the
year, reecting relatively attractive yields on
alternative investments.
The eective federal funds rate moved up
toward the IOER rate in the months before
the June FOMC meeting and, therefore,
was trading near the top of the target range.
At its June meeting, the Committee made a
small technical adjustment in its approach
to implementing monetary policy by setting
the IOER rate modestly below the top of the
target range for the federal funds rate. This
adjustment resulted in the eective federal
funds rate running closer to the middle of the
target range since mid-June. In an environment
of large reserve balances, the IOER rate has
been an essential policy tool for keeping the
federal funds rate within the target range set by
the FOMC (see the box “Interest on Reserves
and Its Importance for Monetary Policy”).
44 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
(continued)
As the economic expansion continued and
unemployment declined—and with labor market
conditions projected to continue improving—the
FOMC decided that it would scale back policy
support by increasing the level of short-term interest
rates and by reducing the Federal Reserve’s securities
holdings. To that end, the Committee began gradually
raising its target range for the federal funds rate in
December2015. Later, in October2017, it began
gradually reducing holdings of Treasury and agency
securities; this gradual reduction results in a decline in
the supply of reserve balances. The FOMC judged that
removing monetary policy stimulus through this mix of
rst raising the federal funds rate and then beginning
to shrink the balance sheet would best contribute to
achieving and maintaining maximum employment and
price stability without causing dislocations in nancial
markets or institutions that could put the economic
expansion at risk.
Interest on reserves—the payment of interest on
balances held by banks in their accounts at the Federal
Reserve—has been an essential policy tool that has
permitted the FOMC to achieve a gradual increase in
the federal funds rate in combination with a gradual
reduction in the Fed’s securities holdings and in the
supply of reserve balances.
3
Interest on reserves is a
monetary policy tool used by all of the world’s major
central banks.
Interest on reserves is the principal tool the FOMC
uses to anchor the federal funds rate in the target range.
The federal funds rate, in turn, establishes an important
benchmark for the borrowing and lending decisions
in the banking sector (gure A). When the Federal
Reserve increases the target range for the federal funds
rate and the interest rate it pays on reserve balances,
banks bid up the rates in short-term funding markets
to levels consistent with those increases; rates in other
short-term funding markets—such as commercial
paper rates, Treasury bill rates, and rates on repurchase
The nancial crisis that began in 2007 triggered the
deepest recession in the United States since the Great
Depression. In response, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) cut its target for the federal funds
rate to nearly zero by late 2008. Other short-term
interest rates declined roughly in line with the federal
funds rate. Additional monetary stimulus was necessary
to address the signicant economic downturn and
the associated downward pressure on ination. The
FOMC undertook other monetary policy actions to
put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates,
including large-scale purchases of longer-term Treasury
securities and agency-guaranteed mortgage-backed
securities.
These policy actions made nancial conditions more
accommodative and helped spur an economic recovery
that has become a long-lasting economic expansion.
The unemployment rate has declined from 10percent
to less than 4percent over the course of the recovery
and expansion, and ination has been low and fairly
stable. The FOMC’s actions were critical to fostering
progress toward maximum employment and stable
prices—the statutory goals for the conduct of monetary
policy established by the Congress.
The Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset purchases
had the side effect of generating a sizable increase in
the supply of reserve balances, which are the balances
that banks maintain in their accounts at the Federal
Reserve.
1
From the onset of the nancial crisis in
August2007 until October2014, when the FOMC
ended the last of its asset purchase programs, the
supply of reserve balances rose from about $15billion
to about $2½trillion.
2
Reserve balances rose well
above the level necessary to meet reserve requirements,
thus swelling the quantity of excess reserves held by the
banking system.
Interest on Reserves and Its Importance for Monetary Policy
1. All depository institutions (commercial banks, savings
banks, thrift institutions, credit unions, and most U.S. branches
and agencies of foreign banks) that maintain reserve balances
are eligible to earn interest on those balances. We refer to
these institutions as “banks.
2. For a detailed discussion of how the changes in Federal
Reserve securities holdings affect the Federal Reserve’s
balance sheet and sectors of the U.S. economy, see Jane
Ihrig, Lawrence Mize, and Gretchen C. Weinbach (2017),
“How Does the Fed Adjust Its Securities Holdings and Who Is
Affected?” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-
099 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, September), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/
feds/les/2017099pap.pdf.
3. The Financial Services Regulatory Relief Act of 2006
authorized the Federal Reserve Banks to pay interest on
balances held by or on behalf of depository institutions at
Federal Reserve Banks, subject to regulations of the Board of
Governors, effective October1, 2011. The effective date of this
authority was changed to October1, 2008, by the Emergency
Economic Stabilization Act of 2008. The Congress authorized
the payment of interest on reserves to help minimize the
incentives for costly reserve avoidance schemes and to provide
the Federal Reserve with a policy tool that could be useful for
monetary policy implementation more broadly.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 45
is higher than the interest it pays on reserve balances.
Each year, the Federal Reserve remits its earnings—
that is, its income net of expenses—to the Treasury
Department; in 2017, remittances totaled more than
$80billion.
Had the Federal Reserve not been able to pay
interest on reserve balances at the same time that
excess reserves in the banking system were large, it
would not have been able to gradually raise the federal
funds rate and other short-term interest rates while
reserve balances were abundant; the FOMC would
have had to take a different approach to scaling back
monetary policy accommodation. This approach likely
would have involved a rapid and sizable reduction
in the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings in order
to put sufcient upward pressure on interest rates.
agreements—all tend to move higher as well (gure B).
This increase in the general level of short-term rates,
together with the expected future path of short-term
rates, then inuences the level of other nancial asset
prices and overall nancial conditions in the economy.
Thus, changing the interest rate on reserves has proven
to be an effective tool for transmitting changes in the
FOMC’s target range for the federal funds rate to other
interest rates in the economy.
The rate of interest the Federal Reserve pays on
banks’ reserve balances is far lower than the rate that
banks can earn on alternative safe assets, including
most U.S. government or agency securities, municipal
securities, and loans to businesses and consumers.
4
Indeed, the bank prime rate—the base rate that banks
use for loans to many of their customers—is currently
around 300 basis points above the level of interest on
reserves. Banks continue to nd lending attractive,
and bank lending has been expanding at a solid pace
since 2012. Households have begun to see interest
rates on retail deposits rising as well. Moreover, the
conguration of interest rates implies that the return
the Federal Reserve earns on its holdings of securities
Eurodollar
Treasury GCF repo
Federal funds
0
25
50
75
100
125
150
175
200
225
250
Basis points
201820172016
A. Overnight money market rates
Daily
Interest on reserves
NOTE: The upper bound of the target range is the interest on reserves
rate
until
June 13, 2018, after which it is 5 basis points higher. The federal
funds
and Eurodollar rates closely track one another over the period shown. GCF is
General Collateral Finance.
SOURCE: For Treasury GCF repo, DTCC Solutions LLC, an affiliate of
The
Depository
Trust & Clearing Corporation; for federal funds, Federal Reserv
e
Bank
of New York; for Eurodollar, Bloomberg; for interest on reserves
and
target range, Federal Reserve Board.
Target range
3-month Treasury bill
3-month AA financial
commercial paper
0
25
50
75
100
125
150
175
200
225
250
Basis points
201820172016
B. Term money market rates
Daily
Interest on reserves
NOTE: The upper bound of the target range is the interest on reserves
rate
until June 13, 2018, after which it is 5 basis points higher.
SOURCE: For U.S. Treasury bill, Department of the Treasury; for
AA
financial
commercial paper, interest on reserves, and target range,
Federal
Reserve Board.
Target range
(continued on next page)
4. The Congress’s authorization allows the Federal
Reserve to pay interest on deposits maintained by depository
institutions at a rate not to exceed the “general level of
short-term interest rates.The Federal Reserve Board’s
RegulationD denes short-term interest rates for the purposes
of this authority as “rates on obligations with maturities of
no more than one year, such as the primary credit rate and
rates on term federal funds, term repurchase agreements,
commercial paper, term Eurodollar deposits, and other similar
instruments.The rate of interest on reserves has been well
within a range of short-term interest rates as dened in Board
regulations. For current rates on a number of short-term money
market instruments, see Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Statistical Release H.15, “Selected Interest
Rates,www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/current.
46 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
yet known, that level is likely to be much lower than it
is today, though appreciably higher than it was before
the crisis.
6
In addition, the amount of U.S. currency—
Federal Reserve notes—that people in the United States
and elsewhere want to hold has increased substantially
since the crisis. If banks want to hold more reserve
balances and the public wants to hold more U.S.
currency than before the crisis, the Federal Reserve will
need to supply the reserves and currency, so the Federal
Reserve’s securities holdings also will have to be larger
than before the nancial crisis.
7
Interest on reserves will remain an important policy
tool for keeping the federal funds rate within the target
range set by the FOMC and thus managing the level of
short-term interest rates, even as the ongoing reduction
in the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings generates a
gradual decline in the amount of reserve balances on
which the Federal Reserve pays interest. In June2018,
the Federal Reserve made a small technical adjustment
to de-link the rate of interest on reserves from the top
of the Committee’s target range for the federal funds
rate. At the June2018 FOMC meeting, the Committee
increased the federal funds target range by 25 basis
points, while the rate of interest on reserve balances
was increased by 20 basis points. This change is
intended to ensure that the federal funds rate continues
to trade well within the Committee’s target range. The
spread between the effective federal funds rate and the
rate of interest on reserves could continue to narrow
over time as the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings
and the supply of reserve balances gradually decline.
Getting the pace of asset sales just right for achieving
the Federal Reserve’s objectives would have been
extremely challenging. Such an approach to removing
accommodation would have run the risk of disrupting
nancial markets, with adverse effects on the economy.
Indeed, as observed during the early summer of
2013, market reactions to changes in the outlook for
the Federal Reserve’s holdings of long-term securities
can have outsized effects in bond markets. At that time,
FOMC communications that pointed to the eventual
cessation of asset purchases seemed to alarm investors
and reportedly contributed to a rise in longer-term rates
of 150 basis points over just a few months. That rise in
rates quickly pushed up the cost of mortgage credit and
rates on other forms of borrowing for households and
businesses.
Thus, Federal Reserve policymakers judged that
the best strategy for adjusting the stance of monetary
policy would be gradual increases in the target range
for the federal funds rate, supplemented later on by
gradual reductions in the Federal Reserve’s securities
holdings. The ongoing, gradual reduction in the Federal
Reserve’s securities holdings that the FOMC set in
motion in 2017 will bring the level of reserve balances
down substantially over the next few years. The size
of reserves that banks eventually want to hold will
reect balances held to meet reserve requirements and
payments needs as well as balances held to address
regulatory and structural changes in the banking system
since the nancial crisis.
5
Although the level of reserve
balances that banks will eventually want to hold is not
Interest on Reserves (continued)
5. For a discussion of the changes in the banking system
since the nancial crisis and their potential effects on the
demand for reserve balances, see Randal K. Quarles (2018),
“Liquidity Regulation and the Size of the Fed’s Balance Sheet,”
speech delivered at “Currencies, Capital, and Central Bank
Balances: A Policy Conference,” Hoover Institution, Stanford
University, Stanford, Calif., May4, https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20180504a.htm.
6. Uncertainty about the eventual level of reserve balances
is another reason that the FOMC has been reducing the
Federal Reserve’s holdings of securities, and the supply of
reserve balances, gradually.
7. Currency grows roughly in line with nominal gross
domestic product. In December2008, currency in circulation
was around $850billion, compared with $1.6trillion at the
end of June2018.
47
In conjunction with the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) meeting held
on June12–13, 2018, meeting participants
submitted their projections of the most likely
outcomes for real gross domestic product
(GDP) growth, the unemployment rate, and
ination for each year from 2018 to 2020
and over the longer run.
17
Each participant’s
projections were based on information
available at the time of the meeting, together
with his or her assessment of appropriate
monetary policy—including a path for the
federal funds rate and its longer-run value—
and assumptions about other factors likely
to aect economic outcomes. The longer-
run projections represent each participant’s
assessment of the value to which each variable
would be expected to converge, over time,
under appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks to the economy.
18
Appropriate monetary policy” is dened as
the future path of policy that each participant
deems most likely to foster outcomes for
economic activity and ination that best
satisfy his or her individual interpretation of
the statutory mandate to promote maximum
employment and price stability.
All participants who submitted longer-run
projections expected that, in 2018, real GDP
would expand at a pace exceeding their
individual estimates of the longer-run growth
rate of real GDP. Participants generally saw
real GDP growth moderating somewhat in
each of the following two years but remaining
above their estimates of the longer-run rate.
17. Three members of the Board of Governors were in
oce at the time of the June2018 meeting.
18. One participant did not submit longer-run
projections for real GDP growth, the unemployment rate,
or the federal funds rate.
All participants who submitted longer-run
projections expected that, throughout the
projection period, the unemployment rate
would run below their estimates of its longer-
run level. All participants projected that
ination, as measured by the four-quarter
percentage change in the price index for
personal consumption expenditures (PCE),
would run at or slightly above the Committee’s
2percent objective by the end of 2018 and
remain roughly at through 2020. Compared
with the Summary of Economic Projections
(SEP) from March, most participants slightly
marked up their projections of real GDP
growth in 2018 and somewhat lowered their
projections for the unemployment rate from
2018 through 2020; participants indicated
that these revisions reected, in large part,
strength in incoming data. A large majority of
participants made slight upward adjustments
to their projections of ination in 2018.
Table1 and gure1 provide summary statistics
for the projections.
As shown in gure2, participants generally
continued to expect that the evolution of
the economy relative to their objectives
of maximum employment and 2percent
ination would likely warrant further gradual
increases in the federal funds rate. The central
tendencies of participants’ projections of the
federal funds rate for both 2018 and 2019
were roughly unchanged, but the medians
for both years were 25 basis points higher
relative to March. Nearly all participants who
submitted longer-run projections expected
that, during part of the projection period,
evolving economic conditions would make it
appropriate for the federal funds rate to move
somewhat above their estimates of its longer-
run level.
Part 3
summary of economic Projections
The following material appeared as an addendum to the minutes of the June12–13, 2018,
meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee.
48 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
In general, participants continued to view
the uncertainty attached to their economic
projections as broadly similar to the
average of the past 20years. As in March,
most participants judged the risks around
their projections for real GDP growth, the
unemployment rate, and ination to be
broadly balanced.
The Outlook for Economic Activity
The median of participants’ projections for
the growth rate of real GDP, conditional on
their individual assessments of appropriate
monetary policy, was 2.8percent for this year
and 2.4percent for next year. The median
was 2.0percent for 2020, a touch above the
median projection of longer-run growth. Most
participants continued to cite scal policy as
a driver of strong economic activity over the
next couple of years. Many participants also
mentioned accommodative monetary policy
and nancial conditions, strength in the global
outlook, continued momentum in the labor
market, or positive readings on business and
consumer sentiment as important factors
shaping the economic outlook. Compared with
the March SEP, the median of participants’
projections for the rate of real GDP growth
was 0.1percentage point higher for this year
and unchanged for the next two years.
Almost all participants expected the
unemployment rate to decline somewhat
further over the projection period. The
median of participants’ projections for the
unemployment rate was 3.6percent for the
nal quarter of this year and 3.5percent
for the nal quarters of 2019 and 2020. The
median of participants’ estimates of the
longer-run unemployment rate was unchanged
at 4.5percent.
Table 1. Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and Federal Reserve Bank presidents,
under their individual assessments of projected appropriate monetary policy, June2018
Percent
Variable
Median
1
Central tendency
2
Range
3
2018 2019 2020
Longer
run
2018 2019 2020
Longer
run
2018 2019 2020
Longer
run
Change in real GDP
..... 2.8 2.4 2.0 1.8 2.7–3.0 2.2–2.6 1.8–2.0 1.8–2.0 2.5–3.0 2.1–2.7 1.5–2.2 1.7–2.1
March projection ...... 2.7 2.4 2.0 1.8 2.6–3.0 2.2–2.6 1.8–2.1 1.8–2.0 2.5–3.0 2.0–2.8 1.5–2.3 1.7–2.2
Unemployment rate
. . . . . . 3.6 3.5 3.5 4.5 3.6–3.7 3.4–3.5 3.4–3.7 4.3–4.6 3.5–3.8 3.3–3.8 3.3–4.0 4.1–4.7
March projection ...... 3.8 3.6 3.6 4.5 3.6–3.8 3.4–3.7 3.5–3.8 4.3–4.7 3.6–4.0 3.3–4.2 3.3–4.4 4.2–4.8
PCE ination
............ 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.0 2.0–2.1 2.0–2.2 2.1–2.2 2.0 2.0–2.2 1.9–2.3 2.0–2.3 2.0
March projection ...... 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.0 1.8–2.0 2.0–2.2 2.1–2.2 2.0 1.8–2.1 1.9–2.3 2.0–2.3 2.0
Core PCE ination
4
...... 2.0 2.1 2.1 1.9–2.0 2.0–2.2 2.1–2.2 1.9–2.1 2.0–2.3 2.0–2.3
March projection ...... 1.9 2.1 2.1 1.8–2.0 2.0–2.2 2.1–2.2 1.8–2.1 1.9–2.3 2.0–2.3
Memo: Projected
appropriate policy path
Federal funds rate
....... 2.4 3.1 3.4 2.9 2.1–2.4 2.9–3.4 3.1–3.6 2.8–3.0 1.9–2.6 1.9–3.6 1.9–4.1 2.3–3.5
March projection ...... 2.1 2.9 3.4 2.9 2.1–2.4 2.8–3.4 3.1–3.6 2.8–3.0 1.6–2.6 1.6–3.9 1.6–4.9 2.3–3.5
N: Projections of change in real gross domestic product (GDP) and projections for both measures of ination are percent changes from the fourth quarter of the previous year to
the fourth quarter of the year indicated. PCE ination and core PCE ination are the percentage rates of change in, respectively, the price index for personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) and the price index for PCE excluding food and energy. Projections for the unemployment rate are for the average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year
indicated. Each participant’s projections are based on his or her assessment of appropriate monetary policy. Longer-run projections represent each participant’s assessment of the rate
to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary policy and in the absence of further shocks to the economy. The projections for the federal funds
rate are the value of the midpoint of the projected appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the projected appropriate target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the
specied calendar year or over the longer run. The March projections were made in conjunction with the meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on March20–21, 2018. One
participant did not submit longer-run projections for the change in real GDP, the unemployment rate, or the federal funds rate in conjunction with the March20–21, 2018, meeting, and
one participant did not submit such projections in conjunction with the June12–13, 2018, meeting.
1.
For each period, the median is the middle projection when the projections are arranged from lowest to highest. When the number of projections is even, the median is the average of
the two middle projections.
2. The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest projections for each variable in each year.
3. The range for a variable in a given year includes all participants’ projections, from lowest to highest, for that variable in that year.
4. Longer-run projections for core PCE ination are not collected.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 49
1
2
3
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Longer
run
Actual
Unemployment rate
3
4
5
6
7
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Longer
run
PCE ination
1
2
3
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Longer
run
Core PCE ination
1
2
3
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Longer
run
Figure 1. Medians, central tendencies, and ranges of economic projections, 2018–20 and over the longer run
Percent
Percent
Percent
Percent
Change in real GDP
Median of projections
Central tendency of projections
Range of projections
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1. The data for the actual values of
the variables are annual.
50 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figures 3.A and 3.B show the distributions of
participants’ projections for real GDP growth
and the unemployment rate from 2018 to 2020
and over the longer run. The distribution of
individual projections for real GDP growth
this year shifted up noticeably from that in the
March SEP. By contrast, the distributions of
projected real GDP growth in 2019 and 2020
and over the longer run were little changed.
The distributions of individual projections for
the unemployment rate in 2018 to 2020
shifted down relative to the distributions
in March, while the downward shift in the
distribution of longer-run projections was
very modest.
The Outlook for Ination
The medians of participants’ projections for
total and core PCE price ination in 2018 were
2.1percent and 2.0percent, respectively, and
the median for each measure was 2.1percent
in 2019 and 2020. Compared with the March
SEP, the medians of participants’ projections
for total PCE price ination for this year and
next were revised up slightly. Some participants
pointed to incoming data on energy prices
as a reason for their upward revisions. The
median of participants’ forecasts for core PCE
price ination was up a touch for this year and
unchanged for subsequent years.
Percent
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
2018 2019 2020 Longer run
Figure 2. FOMC participants’ assessments of appropriate monetary policy: Midpoint of target range or target level
for the federal funds rate
N: Each shaded circle indicates the value (rounded to the nearest 1/8 percentage point) of an individual participant’s
judgment of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal
funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run. One participant did not submit longer-run projections
for the federal funds rate.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 51
Figures 3.C and 3.D provide information on
the distributions of participants’ views about
the outlook for ination. The distributions
of both total and core PCE price ination
for 2018 shifted to the right relative to the
distributions in March. The distributions of
projected ination in 2019, 2020, and over
the longer run were roughly unchanged.
Participants generally expected each measure
to be at or slightly above 2percent in
2019 and 2020.
Appropriate Monetary Policy
Figure 3.E provides the distribution of
participants’ judgments regarding the
appropriate target—or midpoint of the target
range—for the federal funds rate at the end
of each year from 2018 to 2020 and over the
longer run. The distributions of projected
policy rates through 2020 shifted modestly
higher, consistent with the revisions to
participants’ projections of real GDP growth,
the unemployment rate, and ination. As
in their March projections, a large majority
of participants anticipated that evolving
economic conditions would likely warrant
the equivalent of a total of either three or
four increases of 25 basis points in the target
range for the federal funds rate over 2018.
There was a slight reduction in the dispersion
of participants’ views, with no participant
regarding the appropriate target at the end of
the year to be below 1.88percent. For each
subsequent year, the dispersion of participants’
year-end projections was somewhat smaller
than that in the March SEP.
The medians of participants’ projections
of the federal funds rate rose gradually to
2.4percent at the end of this year, 3.1percent
at the end of 2019, and 3.4percent at the end
of 2020. The median of participants’ longer-
run estimates, at 2.9percent, was unchanged
relative to the March SEP.
In discussing their projections, many
participants continued to express the view
that the appropriate trajectory of the federal
funds rate over the next few years would
likely involve gradual increases. This view
was predicated on several factors, including a
judgment that a gradual path of policy rming
likely would appropriately balance the risks
associated with, among other considerations,
the possibilities that U.S. scal policy could
have larger or more persistent positive eects
on real activity and that shifts in trade policy
or developments abroad could weigh on
the expansion. As always, the appropriate
path of the federal funds rate would depend
on evolving economic conditions and their
implications for participants’ economic
outlooks and assessments of risks.
Uncertainty and Risks
In assessing the path for the federal funds rate
that, in their view, is likely to be appropriate,
FOMC participants take account of the range
of possible economic outcomes, the likelihood
of those outcomes, and the potential benets
and costs should they occur. As a reference,
table2 provides measures of forecast
uncertainty, based on the forecast errors of
various private and government forecasts
over the past 20years, for real GDP growth,
the unemployment rate, and total PCE price
ination. Those measures are represented
Variable 2018 2019 2020
Change in real GDP
1
.......
±1.3 ±2.0 ±2.1
Unemployment rate
1
....... ±0.4 ±1.2 ±1.8
Total consumer prices
2
..... ±0.7 ±1.0 ±1.0
Short-term interest rates
3
... ±0.7 ±2.0 ±2.2
N: Error ranges shown are measured as plus or minus the root mean squared
error of projections for 1998 through 2017 that were released in the summer by var-
ious private and government forecasters. As described in the box “Forecast Uncer-
tainty,” under certain assumptions, there is about a 70percent probability that actual
outcomes for real GDP, unemployment, consumer prices, and the federal funds rate
will be in ranges implied by the average size of projection errors made in the past.
For more information, see David Reifschneider and Peter Tulip (2017), “Gauging
the Uncertainty of the Economic Outlook Using Historical Forecasting Errors: The
Federal Reserve’s Approach,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-020
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February), www
.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/feds/2017/files/2017020pap.pdf.
1. Denitions of variables are in the general note to table1.
2. Measure is the overall consumer price index, the price measure that has been
most widely used in government and private economic forecasts. Projections are
percent changes on a fourth quarter to fourth quarter basis.
3. For Federal Reserve sta forecasts, measure is the federal funds rate. For
other forecasts, measure is the rate on 3-month Treasury bills. Projection errors are
calculated using average levels, in percent, in the fourth quarter.
Table 2. Average historical projection error ranges
Percentage points
52 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 3.A. Distribution of participants’ projections for the change in real GDP, 2018–20 and over the longer run
2018
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0
1.5 1.7 1.9 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 3.1
Percent range
June projections
March projections
2019
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
2020
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
Longer run
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0
1.5 1.7 1.9 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 3.1
1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0
1.5 1.7 1.9 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 3.1
1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0
1.5 1.7 1.9 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 3.1
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 53
Figure 3.B. Distribution of participants’ projections for the unemployment rate, 2018–20 and over the longer run
2018
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
3.0– 3.2– 3.4– 3.6– 3.8– 4.0– 4.2– 4.4– 4.6– 4.8– 5.0–
3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.9 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.7 4.9 5.1
Percent range
June projections
March projections
2019
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
2020
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
Longer run
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
3.0– 3.2– 3.4– 3.6– 3.8– 4.0– 4.2– 4.4– 4.6– 4.8– 5.0–
3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.9 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.7 4.9 5.1
3.0– 3.2– 3.4– 3.6– 3.8– 4.0– 4.2– 4.4– 4.6– 4.8– 5.0–
3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.9 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.7 4.9 5.1
3.0– 3.2– 3.4– 3.6– 3.8– 4.0– 4.2– 4.4– 4.6– 4.8– 5.0–
3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.9 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.7 4.9 5.1
54 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 3.C. Distribution of participants’ projections for PCE ination, 2018–20 and over the longer run
2018
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
June projections
March projections
2019
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
2020
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
Longer run
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 55
Figure 3.D. Distribution of participants’ projections for core PCE ination, 2018–20
2018
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
June projections
March projections
2019
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
2020
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
1.7– 1.9– 2.1– 2.3–
1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
56 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2018
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
June projections
March projections
2019
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
2020
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
Longer run
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Percent range
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
Figure 3.E. Distribution of participants’ judgments of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal
funds ra
te or the appropriate target level for the federal funds rate, 2018–20 and over the longer run
Number of participants
Number of participants
Number of participants
Number of participants
1.63–
1.87
1.88–
2.12
2.13–
2.37
2.38–
2.62
2.63–
2.87
2.88–
3.12
3.13–
3.37
3.38–
3.62
3.63–
3.87
3.88–
4.12
4.13–
4.37
4.38–
4.62
4.63–
4.87
4.88–
5.12
1.63–
1.87
1.88–
2.12
2.13–
2.37
2.38–
2.62
2.63–
2.87
2.88–
3.12
3.13–
3.37
3.38–
3.62
3.63–
3.87
3.88–
4.12
4.13–
4.37
4.38–
4.62
4.63–
4.87
4.88–
5.12
1.63–
1.87
1.88–
2.12
2.13–
2.37
2.38–
2.62
2.63–
2.87
2.88–
3.12
3.13–
3.37
3.38–
3.62
3.63–
3.87
3.88–
4.12
4.13–
4.37
4.38–
4.62
4.63–
4.87
4.88–
5.12
1.63–
1.87
1.88–
2.12
2.13–
2.37
2.38–
2.62
2.63–
2.87
2.88–
3.12
3.13–
3.37
3.38–
3.62
3.63–
3.87
3.88–
4.12
4.13–
4.37
4.38–
4.62
4.63–
4.87
4.88–
5.12
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 57
graphically in the “fan charts” shown in
the top panels of gures 4.A, 4.B, and 4.C.
The fan charts display the median SEP
projections for the three variables surrounded
by symmetric condence intervals derived
from the forecast errors reported in table2.
If the degree of uncertainty attending these
projections is similar to the typical magnitude
of past forecast errors and the risks around the
projections are broadly balanced, then future
outcomes of these variables would have about
a 70percent probability of being within these
condence intervals. For all three variables,
this measure of uncertainty is substantial and
generally increases as the forecast horizon
lengthens.
Participants’ assessments of the level of
uncertainty surrounding their individual
economic projections are shown in the
bottom-left panels of gures4.A, 4.B,
and 4.C. Nearly all participants viewed
the degree of uncertainty attached to their
economic projections for real GDP growth,
the unemployment rate, and ination as
broadly similar to the average of the past
20years, a view that was essentially unchanged
from March.
19
Because the fan charts are constructed to be
symmetric around the median projections,
they do not reect any asymmetries in the
balance of risks that participants may see
in their economic projections. Participants’
assessments of the balance of risks to their
economic projections are shown in the
bottom-right panels of gures4.A, 4.B, and
4.C. Most participants judged the risks to
their projections of real GDP growth, the
unemployment rate, total ination, and core
ination as broadly balanced—in other words,
as broadly consistent with a symmetric fan
chart. Compared with March, even more
19. At the end of this summary, the box “Forecast
Uncertainty” discusses the sources and interpretation
of uncertainty surrounding the economic forecasts and
explains the approach used to assess the uncertainty and
risks attending the participants’ projections.
participants saw the risks to their projections
as broadly balanced. Specically, for GDP
growth, only one participant viewed the risks
as tilted to the downside, and the number of
participants who viewed the risks as tilted
to the upside dropped from four to two.
For the unemployment rate, the number of
participants who saw the risks as tilted toward
low readings dropped from four to two. For
ination, all but one participant judged the
risks to either total or core PCE price ination
as broadly balanced.
In discussing the uncertainty and risks
surrounding their projections, several
participants continued to point to scal
developments as a source of upside risk,
many participants cited developments related
to trade policy as posing downside risks to
their growth forecasts, and a few participants
also pointed to political developments in
Europe or the global outlook more generally
as downside-risk factors. A few participants
noted that the appreciation of the dollar
posed downside risks to the ination outlook.
A few participants also noted the risk of
ination moving higher than anticipated as the
unemployment rate falls.
Participants’ assessments of the appropriate
future path of the federal funds rate were also
subject to considerable uncertainty. Because
the Committee adjusts the federal funds
rate in response to actual and prospective
developments over time in real GDP growth,
the unemployment rate, and ination,
uncertainty surrounding the projected path
for the federal funds rate importantly reects
the uncertainties about the paths for those
key economic variables. Figure5 provides a
graphical representation of this uncertainty,
plotting the median SEP projection for the
federal funds rate surrounded by condence
intervals derived from the results presented
in table2. As with the macroeconomic
variables, forecast uncertainty surrounding the
appropriate path of the federal funds rate is
substantial and increases for longer horizons.
58 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Change in real GDP
Percent
0
1
2
3
4
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Risks to GDP growth
Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Weighted to
upside
Weighted to
downside
June projections
March projections
Figure 4.A. Uncertainty and risks in projections of GDP growth
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty and risks around their economic projections
Lower HigherBroadly
Similar
Broadly
balanced
Uncertainty about GDP growth
N
: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the percent change
in real gross domestic product (GDP) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The
condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean
squared errors of
various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2.
Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the
condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments
of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally
speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past
20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments
of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced”
would view the condence interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in
economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 59
Figure 4.B. Uncertainty and risks in projections of the unemployment rate
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
Unemployment rate
Percent
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty and risks around their economic projections
Uncertainty about the unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Risks to the unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Number of participants Number of participants
Weighted to
upside
Weighted to
downside
Lower HigherBroadly
Similar
Broadly
balanced
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the average
civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected
values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made
over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from
those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis
of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around
their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the
uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the
condence interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their
projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence
interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections,
see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
60 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 4.C. Uncertainty and risks in projections of PCE ination
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
PCE ination
0
1
2
3
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Median of projections
70% condence interval
Actual
FOMC participants’ assessments of uncertainty and risks around their economic projections
Uncertainty about PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Uncertainty about core PCE ination
Number of participants Number of participants
Number of participants Number of participants
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Risks to PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Risks to core PCE ination
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
June projections
March projections
Weighted to
upside
Weighted to
downside
Lower HigherBroadly
Similar
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
Weighted to
downside
Lower HigherBroadly
Similar
Broadly
balanced
Percent
N
: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the percent change
in the price inde
x for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth quarter
of
the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root
mean squa
red errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these
da
ta is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous
20 years
, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect
FOMC participants’
current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are
summariz
ed in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly
similar”
to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan
chart as lar
gely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants who judge
the risks to their pr
ojections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence interval around their projections as approximately
symmetric. F
or denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2018 61
Figure 5. Uncertainty in projections of the federal funds rate
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
Federal funds rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Midpoint of target range
Median of projections
70% condence interval*
Actual
Percent
N
: The blue and red lines are based on actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the Committee’s target for
the feder
al funds rate at the end of the year indicated. The actual values are the midpoint of the target range; the median projected
va
lues are based on either the midpoint of the target range or the target level. The condence interval around the median proje
cted
va
lues is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years. The
condence interv
al is not strictly consistent with the projections for the federal funds rate, primarily because these projections are
not
forecasts of the likeliest outcomes for the federal funds rate, but rather projections of participants’ individual assessments of
a
ppropriate monetary policy. Still, historical forecast errors provide a broad sense of the uncertainty around the future path of the
feder
al funds rate generated by the uncertainty about the macroeconomic variables as well as additional adjustments to monetary
policy th
at may be appropriate to oset the eects of shocks to the economy.
The condence interval is assumed to be symmetric except when it is truncated at zero—the bottom of the lowest tar
get range
fo
r the federal funds rate that has been adopted in the past by the Committee. This truncation would not be intended to indicat
e
the li
kelihood of the use of negative interest rates to provide additional monetary policy accommodation if
doing so was judged
a
ppropriate. In such situations, the Committee could also employ other tools, including forward guidance and large-scale asset
pur
chases, to provide additional accommodation. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average,
ov
er the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors
ma
y not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections.
* The condence interval is derived from forecasts of the average level of short-term interest rates in the fourth quarter of
the year
indica
ted; more information about these data is available in table 2. The shaded area encompasses less than a 70 percent condence
interval if the condence interval has been truncated at zero.
62 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
in the bottom-left panels of those gures. Participants
also provide judgments as to whether the risks to their
projections are weighted to the upside, are weighted to
the downside, or are broadly balanced. That is, while the
symmetric historical fan charts shown in the top panels of
gures4.A through 4.C imply that the risks to participants’
projections are balanced, participants may judge that
there is a greater risk that a given variable will be above
rather than below their projections. These judgments
are summarized in the lower-right panels of gures 4.A
through 4.C.
As with real activity and ination, the outlook for
the future path of the federal funds rate is subject to
considerable uncertainty. This uncertainty arises primarily
because each participants assessment of the appropriate
stance of monetary policy depends importantly on
the evolution of real activity and ination over time. If
economic conditions evolve in an unexpected manner,
then assessments of the appropriate setting of the federal
funds rate would change from that point forward. The
nal line in table2 shows the error ranges for forecasts of
short-term interest rates. They suggest that the historical
condence intervals associated with projections of the
federal funds rate are quite wide. It should be noted,
however, that these condence intervals are not strictly
consistent with the projections for the federal funds
rate, as these projections are not forecasts of the most
likely quarterly outcomes but rather are projections
of participants’ individual assessments of appropriate
monetary policy and are on an end-of-year basis.
However, the forecast errors should provide a sense of the
uncertainty around the future path of the federal funds rate
generated by the uncertainty about the macroeconomic
variables as well as additional adjustments to monetary
policy that would be appropriate to offset the effects of
shocks to the economy.
If at some point in the future the condence interval
around the federal funds rate were to extend below zero,
it would be truncated at zero for purposes of the fan chart
shown in gure5; zero is the bottom of the lowest target
range for the federal funds rate that has been adopted
by the Committee in the past. This approach to the
construction of the federal funds rate fan chart would be
merely a convention; it would not have any implications
for possible future policy decisions regarding the use of
negative interest rates to provide additional monetary
policy accommodation if doing so were appropriate. In
such situations, the Committee could also employ other
tools, including forward guidance and asset purchases, to
provide additional accommodation.
While gures 4.A through 4.C provide information on
the uncertainty around the economic projections, gure1
provides information on the range of views across FOMC
participants. A comparison of gure1 with gures4.A
through 4.C shows that the dispersion of the projections
across participants is much smaller than the average
forecast errors over the past 20years.
The economic projections provided by the members of
the Board of Governors and the presidents of the Federal
Reserve Banks inform discussions of monetary policy
among policymakers and can aid public understanding
of the basis for policy actions. Considerable uncertainty
attends these projections, however. The economic and
statistical models and relationships used to help produce
economic forecasts are necessarily imperfect descriptions
of the real world, and the future path of the economy
can be affected by myriad unforeseen developments and
events. Thus, in setting the stance of monetary policy,
participants consider not only what appears to be the
most likely economic outcome as embodied in their
projections, but also the range of alternative possibilities,
the likelihood of their occurring, and the potential costs to
the economy should they occur.
Table 2 summarizes the average historical accuracy
of a range of forecasts, including those reported in past
Monetary Policy Reports and those prepared by the
Federal Reserve Board’s staff in advance of meetings of the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). The projection
error ranges shown in the table illustrate the considerable
uncertainty associated with economic forecasts. For
example, suppose a participant projects that real gross
domestic product (GDP) and total consumer prices will
rise steadily at annual rates of, respectively, 3percent and
2percent. If the uncertainty attending those projections
is similar to that experienced in the past and the risks
around the projections are broadly balanced, the numbers
reported in table2 would imply a probability of about
70percent that actual GDP would expand within a range
of 1.7 to 4.3percent in the current year, 1.0 to 5.0percent
in the second year, and 0.9 to 5.1percent in the third
year. The corresponding 70percent condence intervals
for overall ination would be 1.3 to 2.7percent in the
current year and 1.0 to 3.0percent in the second and third
years. Figures 4.A through 4.C illustrate these condence
bounds in “fan charts” that are symmetric and centered on
the medians of FOMC participants’ projections for GDP
growth, the unemployment rate, and ination. However,
in some instances, the risks around the projections may
not be symmetric. In particular, the unemployment rate
cannot be negative; furthermore, the risks around a
particular projection might be tilted to either the upside or
the downside, in which case the corresponding fan chart
would be asymmetrically positioned around the median
projection.
Because current conditions may differ from those that
prevailed, on average, over history, participants provide
judgments as to whether the uncertainty attached to
their projections of each economic variable is greater
than, smaller than, or broadly similar to typical levels
of forecast uncertainty seen in the past 20years, as
presented in table2 and reected in the widths of the
condence intervals shown in the top panels of gures
4.A through 4.C. Participants’ current assessments of the
uncertainty surrounding their projections are summarized
Forecast Uncertainty
63
AFE advanced foreign economy
BBA Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018
BLS Bureau of Labor Statistics
C&I commercial and industrial
Desk Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
DPI disposable personal income
ECB European Central Bank
EME emerging market economy
FOMC Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee
GDP gross domestic product
IOER interest on excess reserves
JOLTS Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
LFPR labor force participation rate
MBS mortgage-backed securities
Michigan survey University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers
OIS overnight index swap
ON RRP overnight reverse repurchase agreement
PCE personal consumption expenditures
SEP Summary of Economic Projections
SLOOS Senior Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices
S&P Standard & Poor’s
TCJA Tax Cuts and Jobs Act
TIPS Treasury Ination-Protected Securities
VIX implied volatility for the S&P 500 index
abbreviations
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m., EDT
July 13, 2018
Monetary Policy rePort
July 13, 2018