FEDERAL-STATE INCOME TAX PROGRESSIVITY
Frank Sammartino and Norton Francis
June 2016
ABSTRACT
This report finds that both federal and state income taxes are generally progressive but (1) state systems
are much less progressive than the federal system and (2) the degree of progressivity varies widely among
the states. Federal income taxes became more progressive following 2012 legislation that increased high-
income tax rates. The higher federal tax rates also increased the subsidy provided by the federal deduction
for state income taxes. Despite this incentive for states to raise their own income tax rates, more states
lowered tax rates than raised them. Nonetheless, there was little change in the overall progressivity of state
income taxes.
We would like to thank John Iselin and Elena Ramirez for excellent research assistance; Richard
Auxier, Harvey Galper, Tracy Gordon, Rob McClellan, Kim Rueben, Eric Toder, and Roberton
Williams for comments on earlier versions of this paper; and Lydia Austin for preparing the
document for publication.
Financial support for developing the state weighting methodology and producing this report has
been generously supported by a grant from the Stoneman Family Foundation. We thank our
funders who make it possible for the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center and the Urban Institute
to advance their mission. The findings and conclusions contained in this report are those of the
authors and do not necessarily reflect positions or policies of the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy
Center, the Urban Institute, or their funders.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 1
SUMMARY AND INTRODUCTION
Both the federal and state income tax systems are generally progressive: the fraction of income
paid in taxes rises with income. Several features common to the federal and most state systems
contribute to the progressivity of income taxes, including graduated marginal tax rates (tax rates
that are higher in higher income tax brackets) and exemptions, deductions, and credits targeted
toward low- and moderate-income households.
Federal and state income taxes are linked in many ways, but most directly through the
federal deduction for state and local taxes. Taxpayers who itemize their federal deductions can
deduct state and local real estate taxes, personal property taxes, and either income or sales taxes
in calculating their federal taxable income. Taxpayers subject to the federal alternative minimum
tax (AMT), however, lose the deduction.
Because the likelihood of itemizing, the amount of state taxes paid, and the tax savings
from each dollar deducted all rise with income, the federal deduction reduces the progressivity
of federal income taxes. But the deduction may also cause state income taxes to be more
progressive than they otherwise would be. Because the federal government reimburses
taxpayers for some portion of the state income taxes they pay and because that subsidy rises
with income, states can raise income tax rates on high-income taxpayers, increasing the
progressivity of their state income taxes, without those taxpayers bearing the full cost of the tax
increase.
In this report we examine the progressivity of federal and state income taxes, using a
sample of federal individual income tax returns with state representative weights. We calculate
federal and state income taxes and analyze the distribution of those taxes across household
income groups in 2011. We also explore how that distribution changed under 2014 tax rules
following enactment of the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (ATRA) at the federal level and
the many changes to state income laws enacted between 2011 and 2014.
Federal income taxes are much more progressive than state income taxes. We find that in
2011 the average federal individual income tax rate ranged from about -5 percent in the lowest
income quintile to 13 percent in the highest income quintile and to 20 percent for the 1 percent
of people with the very highest incomes.
1
The average federal tax rate is negative in the lowest
income quintile because refundable tax credits exceeded the amount of income tax liability for
those households. In contrast, the overall average state individual income tax rate in 2011
ranged from zero for the lowest quintile to 3 percent for the highest income quintile and to just
over 4 percent for the top 1 percent.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 2
We also calculate two tax progressivity indexes for federal and state income taxes
separately and combined, and for state income taxes in each of the 43 states with an individual
income tax and the District of Columbia (DC). These indexes measure the progressivity of taxes
in different ways; the first compares the distribution of income before and after income taxes
and the second measures the concentration of income tax payments across households ranked
by income. Not surprisingly, we find a great deal of variation in income tax progressivity across
the states, though all state income tax systems are progressive to some degree according to both
indexes.
Income taxes, however, are just one part of both the federal and state tax systems. Other
taxes, notably federal payroll and excise taxes, and state sales taxes, are either less progressive
than income taxes or regressive (with lower-income households paying a larger share of their
income than higher-income households). A complete assessment of the progressivity of federal
and state tax systems would include all taxes.
2
Federal income taxes became more progressive following passage of ATRA. The act
permanently extended the temporary lower tax rates that were put in place in 2001 and 2003,
but allowed the tax rate on income over $400,000 ($450,000 for couples), to revert to its higher
pre-2001 level. One consequence of the higher federal tax rate was an increase in the implicit
federal subsidy for state income taxes because each dollar of state income taxes claimed as a
federal deduction by taxpayers in the highest federal tax bracket led to a larger reduction in
federal income taxes.
States could have taken advantage of this increased subsidy by raising state income tax
rates for high-income taxpayers affected by the federal change, but most did not. In fact, many
states did just the opposite, cutting tax rates across the board or reducing only the top tax rates.
Consequently, we find that although federal income taxes became more progressive between
2011 and 2014 the overall progressivity of state income taxes was unchanged, although income
tax progressivity increased in a small number of states and decreased in others.
OVERVIEW OF FEDERAL AND STATE INCOME TAXES
Individual income taxes are the largest single source of federal revenue, accounting for 47
percent of total revenue in 2015. Individual income taxes also are the most significant factor
contributing to the progressivity of total federal taxes. Other tax sources, such as estate and gift
taxes, may be more progressive than individual income taxes, but their comparatively modest
size limits their contribution to overall federal tax progressivity.
Multiple features contribute to the progressivity of federal income taxes. Graduated
marginal tax rates (tax rates on additional dollars of income that are higher in higher income tax
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 3
brackets) raise average tax rates (taxes divided by before-tax income) as income increases.
Deductions and exemptions that apply equally to all taxpayers regardless of their income, such as
the standard deduction and personal exemptions (up to certain income limits), reduce average
tax rates more for middle- and lower-income households than for higher-income households.
3
Finally, credits that phase out at higher incomes, such as the child tax credit (CTC), the child and
dependent care tax credit (CDCTC), and the earned income tax credit (EITC) reduce or eliminate
taxes for moderate- and low-income households. The federal EITC and the CTC (with certain
restrictions) are refundable: taxpayers receive credits in excess of their income tax liability as a
payment from the government, further increasing federal income tax progressivity. Although
average income tax rates for households receiving refundable credits can be less than zero, their
overall average federal tax rate may be greater than zero because they also pay payroll and other
federal taxes.
Some features of the federal income tax system tend to reduce the progressivity of
federal income taxes, however. Among these are reduced tax rates on capital gains and dividends
(income disproportionately received by higher-income households) and the option to itemize
deductions rather than claim a standard deduction.
4
In contrast to federal revenue, individual income taxes account for a modest share of state
revenueabout 18 percent of state general revenue overall.
5
Forty-three states and DC have
individual income taxes. The definition of taxable income varies by state, but most states levy
income taxes on a broad income base that generally follows the federal system. New Hampshire
and Tennessee tax only income from dividends and interest. Alaska, Florida, Nevada, South
Dakota, Texas, Washington, and Wyoming do not tax personal income.
State income taxes mirror many of the features in the federal system. Of the 41 states
with a broad-based income tax, 33 have a graduated rate structure with multiple tax brackets
and rates, as does DC; 8 states (Colorado, Illinois, Indiana, Massachusetts, Michigan, North
Carolina, Pennsylvania, and Utah) apply a single tax rate.
6
Top marginal tax rates for state income
taxes in 2016 range from 2.9 percent in North Dakota to 13.3 percent in California, including the
additional 1 percent surcharge on income over $1 million levied in that state. Most state income
taxes are fairly flat, even in those states that apply graduated tax rates. In several states the top
tax bracket begins at a very low level of taxable income. Alabama, for example, starts its top rate
at taxable income above $3,000 ($6,000 for couples). In other states the difference between the
lowest and the highest tax rates is small, for example, 2 percentage points or less in Arizona,
Kansas, Maine, Mississippi, and North Dakota.
Like the federal system, most states with broad-based income taxes allow taxpayers to
claim personal exemptions and a standard deduction, though the state amounts often differ from
the federal amounts. Several states use tax credits in place of exemptions and deductions. Unlike
the federal income tax, many state income tax systems tax capital gains and dividends at the
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 4
same rate as other income, a feature that increases state income tax progressivity compared to
the federal system.
A majority of the states also have tax credits targeted toward low-income households.
Twenty-six states and DC have enacted their own EITC, although Washington has not
implemented its credit. All jurisdictions except Minnesota calculate the state credit as a
percentage of the federal credit. Like the federal EITC, the state credit is refundable in most
states but not in Delaware, Ohio, and Virginia. About half the states have their own child and
dependent care tax credit but very few states (only California, New York, North Carolina, and
Oklahoma) have a child tax credit.
In addition to a flatter rate structure, certain features of state income tax systems, such as
special exemptions and deductions, can further reduce their progressivity. Alabama, Iowa,
Louisiana, Missouri, Montana, and Oregon, for example, allow a deduction for federal income
taxes, in effect a subsidy from those states to the federal government.
HOW PROGRESSIVE ARE FEDERAL AND STATE INCOME TAXES?
Both federal and state individual income taxes are progressive, but state taxes are much less so.
In 2011, the average federal individual income tax rate (federal income taxes divided by before-
tax income) ranged from -4.8 percent in the lowest income quintile to 13.1 percent in the highest
quintile and to 20.2 percent for the 1 percent of people with the highest incomes (table 1). The
average federal tax rate was negative in the lowest two income quintiles because, on average,
refundable tax credits exceeded the amount of income tax liability for those households. The
average state individual income tax rate ranged from zero for the lowest quintile to 3.0 percent
for the highest.
7
Average federal individual income taxes were much larger than average state
income taxes; the overall average federal tax rate was 8.1 percent compared with an average
state income tax rate of 2.2 percent for the all the states combined. The overall distribution of
combined federal and state income taxes was progressive, with an average tax rate that ranged
from -4.9 percent for the lowest quintile to 16.2 percent for the highest and to 24.5 percent for
the top 1 percent.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 5
Average Income Tax Rates by State
The average federal income tax rate in 2011, which was 8.1 percent nationally, ranged from 11.3
percent in DC and Connecticut to 4.6 percent in Mississippi (table 2). DC, Connecticut, New
York, and Massachusetts all had an average federal tax rate of 10 percent or more; Mississippi,
Idaho, South Carolina, and Arkansas had an average federal tax rate under 6 percent.
Differences in average federal income tax rates across the country reflect the
demographic and economic diversity among the states including differences in (1) average
household income and its distribution; (2) the composition of income, such as the share from tax-
favored sources such as dividends and capital gains; (3) family sizes and other demographic
characteristics, which determine the value of personal exemptions and certain tax credits; and
(4) the portion of income used for tax-preferred items, such as contributions to tax-favored
retirement and education saving accounts, or for tax-deductible expenditures such as mortgage
interest payments, state and local taxes, and charitable contributions.
TABLE 1
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 6
The overall average state income tax rate (total state income taxes divided by total before
tax income) was 2.2 percent, including the seven states with no income tax (table 2). The average
excluding those seven states was 2.7 percent. Nine states and DC had a rate of 3 percent or
more, with the average state income tax rate at or above 4 percent in DC and Oregon. Ten states
with a broad-based income tax had an average state income tax rate of 2 percent or less. New
Hampshire and Tennessee, which tax only interest and dividends, had an average rate below 0.5
percent. Differences in average state income tax rates across the states reflect structural
differences in state income tax systems as well as the economic and demographic factors
previously mentioned.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 7
TABLE 2
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 8
The average combined federal and state income tax rate was 10.2 percent. It ranged from
15.5 percent in DC to 6.3 percent in Mississippi. States that did not have a state income tax were
not necessarily the states with the lowest combined average tax rate. The average federal tax
rate, which reflects the demographic and economic characteristics of taxpayers in each state,
was in some cases higher in those states than the average combined federal and state income tax
rate in several states with an income tax.
The average state income tax rates we calculate do not include additional income taxes
levied by cities, counties, municipalities, and school districts within the states. According to the
data from the US Census Bureau, only 13 states reported any local income tax revenue in 2013.
8
In seven of those states local income tax revenue was less than 6 percent of combined state and
local income tax revenue, but it was sizable in the remaining six states: local income tax revenue
was 20 percent of combined state and local income tax revenue in Indiana and New York, 24
percent in Kentucky, 30 percent in Pennsylvania, 33 percent in Ohio, and 37 percent in
Maryland.
In some of the states with significant local income tax revenue local taxes apply to all or
nearly all residents. For example, all counties in Maryland and the city of Baltimore levy an
income tax, as do all counties in Indiana, and almost all municipalities and school districts in
Pennsylvania. While not quite as broad, most municipalities and school districts in Ohio and
many cities and counties in Kentucky levy a local income tax. Only two local jurisdictions in New
York levy an income tax: New York City and Yonkers.
Local income taxes in Indiana, Maryland, and New York are levied on the same broad
income base as the state income tax, and taxpayers file a single return for their state and local
taxes. Local income tax rates in Indiana and Maryland generally fall in the range of about 1 to 3
percent. For example, excluding Worcester County (which has a tax rate of 1.25 percent and
contains less than 1 percent of the state’s population) local tax rates for Maryland residents
range from 2.4 percent to 3.2 percent, but about half of Maryland residents live in jurisdictions in
which the local tax rate is 3.2 percent. Local tax rates in New York City range from 2.907 percent
to 3.648 percent, and the local income tax in Yonkers is equal to 16.75 percent of the state
income tax.
Local income taxes in Kentucky and Pennsylvania do not use the same tax base as the
state income tax but instead are levied on earnings and business profits. Local income taxes
levied by school districts in Ohio mostly use the same tax base as state income taxes, but some
only tax earnings. Local income taxes levied by municipalities in Ohio use a different base than
the state income tax.
Local income taxes are less distinguishable from the state income tax in Indiana and
Maryland where they apply to all or nearly all state residents, follow the same tax base as the
state income tax, and are filed on the state income tax return. Including local income taxes in
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 9
those states would raise the average state tax rate approximately 0.4 percentage points in
Indiana and 1.3 percentage points in Maryland. Because Maryland’s state income tax has
graduated rates but local taxes in that states are levied at a single rate (with some variation
across counties), adding local income taxes to the state tax would result in a less progressive rate
schedule. Both the state and local income taxes in Indiana are levied at a single rate with some
variation in rates across counties.
Distribution of State Income Tax Rates by Income
The progressivity of state individual income taxes ranged widely across the states in 2011. To
make comparisons across states, taxpayers in each state are ranked by income according to
national percentiles. For example, we ranked California taxpayers in the highest income quintile
if their income placed them in the 20 percent of the U.S. population with the highest income. The
calculations include only the 41 states and DC with broad-based income taxes. They do not
include local income taxes in those jurisdictions.
The range of average tax rates in the middle income quintile (approximately the tax rate
for the median income taxpayer) was fairly compressed ranging from 0.6 percent in North
Dakota, 0.8 percent in California, and 0.9 percent in New Jersey to 3.0 percent in Oregon. The
average tax rate in the top income quintile was lowest in North Dakota and highest in New York.
The average tax rate in the lowest income quintile was less than zero as a result of refundable tax
credits that exceeded income tax liability in 13 states and DC.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 10
The difference between the average tax rate in the lowest and highest income quintiles
was smallest in Alabama (1.2 percentage points), Pennsylvania (1.5 percentage points), and
North Dakota (1.5 percentage points) and greatest in New York and DC (7 percentage points).
The spread between average tax rates in the lowest and highest income quintiles was
generally lower in 6 of the 7 states with a single tax rate (Colorado, Illinois, Indiana, Michigan,
Pennsylvania, and Utah) than in other states, but that was not always the case. The difference in
average tax rates in Massachusetts, which also has a single tax rate, was among the upper half of
states mostly due to provisions that reduced or eliminated income taxes for low-income
households, such as a no-tax income threshold, a limited income tax credit, and a refundable
earned income tax credit.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 11
Summary Indexes of Income Tax Progressivity
We calculate two statistical indexes to summarize the overall progressivity of taxes. The first is
the Reynolds-Smolensky (RS) index, which compares the concentration of income before and
after taxes. It is calculated as the difference between the Gini coefficient for income before
income taxes and the Gini coefficient for income after income taxes.
9
The second is the Kakwani
(K) index, which compares the concentration of income taxes with the concentration of income
before tax. It is calculated as the difference between the tax concentration index and the Gini
coefficient for before-tax income.
10
If taxes are proportional to before-tax income, the before-tax Gini index will equal the
after-tax Gini index and the RS index will be zero. Likewise, with a proportional tax system, the
distribution of taxes across the population ranked by income will be the same as the distribution
of before-tax income, and the K index will also have a value of zero. In a progressive tax system,
where average tax rates rise with income, both indexes will exceed zero, the RS index because
after-tax income is less concentrated than before-tax income and the K index because taxes are
more concentrated than income.
An important difference between the two measures is that the average tax rate for the
population matters for the RS index, but not for the K index. Thus, a small tax levied only on
millionaires would have little effect on the after-tax distribution of income, yielding a value close
to zero for the RS index, but the concentration of the tax among upper-income taxpayers would
yield a positive value for the K index.
11
The RS index and the K index for federal, state, and combined individual income taxes
summarize the information in the distribution of average tax rates by income quintiles (table 3).
The RS index is positive for both federal and state income taxes but much larger for federal taxes.
Because federal taxes are more progressive than state income taxes and twice the size, they have
a much bigger equalizing effect on the distribution of after-tax income. The K index (the tax
concentration index minus the before-tax Gini coefficient) is also positive for both federal and
state income taxes because both taxes are more concentrated than before-tax income. The index
is larger for federal taxes because higher-income households pay a larger share of federal income
taxes than their share of state income taxes.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 12
Both indexes vary across the states. The RS index is highest in New York, California, DC,
Connecticut, and New Jersey and, among states with broad based income taxes, lowest in
Alabama, Pennsylvania, Illinois, North Dakota, Indiana, and Arizona (figure 2). Income taxes do
more to equalize the distribution of income in states with high index values and less in states with
low values.
TABLE 3
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 13
Among states with a broad-based income tax, the K index is highest in New Mexico,
Vermont, California, New Jersey, Rhode Island, and Maryland; and lowest in Alabama, Illinois,
and Pennsylvania (figure 2). It is worth reiterating that both indexes would look quite different if
we were measuring the effect of all taxes rather than just income taxes.
The results for New Hampshire and Tennessee illustrate the difference between the two
indexes. The K index is much higher and the RS index much lower than the national average in
both states. Because New Hampshire and Tennessee only tax income from dividends and
interest, their tax systems are relatively small and thus have little effect on the distribution of
income, which results in a low value for the RS index. But income taxes are highly concentrated
among high-income taxpayers in both states, and thus they have a high value for the K index.
New Mexico is another interesting example. It has the highest value for the K index of any
state, but its value for the RS index, while high, is not quite among the top ten. New Mexico’s
income tax has several features that contribute to progressivity and thus cause it to rank high
according to the K index. These include graduated tax rates, personal exemptions and a standard
deduction equal to the federal amounts, additional low- and middle-income personal exemptions,
a lowincome tax rebate, and a 10 percent refundable EITC. However, the average state income
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 14
tax rate in New Mexico was among the lowest among states with a broad-based income tax.
Income taxes thus had a modest effect on the difference between the before-tax and after-tax
distribution of income within the state, causing it to rank somewhat lower according to the RS
index.
INTERACTION BETWEEN FEDERAL AND STATE TAXES
Federal and state income tax systems interact in significant ways. All states take advantage of
federal tax administration and reporting by conforming to the federal rules and definitions for
the income tax base to some degree.
12
Of the 41 states with broad-based individual income
taxes, 29 states and DC start with federal adjusted gross income, 7 start with federal taxable
income, and 5 use their own starting point. In the past, some states went even further by simply
computing state income tax as a percentage of the federal income tax, but no state currently
follows that practice.
Because the federal income tax base is the starting point for state income tax bases,
federal rules governing income exclusions (such as for employer-provided health insurance) and
“above-the-line” adjustments (such as the deduction for student loan interest) directly flow
through to the calculation of state taxable income. The same is true for federal rules concerning
the standard or itemized deductions. Eleven states use the federal standard deduction and 33
states allow itemized deductions based on federal itemized deductions, although most states do
not carry over the federal deduction for state and local taxes.
The federal and state income tax systems interact directly through the SALT deduction.
13
Taxpayers who itemize deductions on their federal income tax returns can deduct certain state
and local taxes from their federal taxable income. These include taxes on real estate, personal
property, and either income taxes or general sales taxes.
14
About 30 percent of tax filers opt to
itemize deductions on their federal returns, and virtually all who do claim a deduction for state
and local taxes paid. State and local income taxes and real estate taxes make up the majority of
the SALT deduction; about 60 percent and 35 percent respectively; sales taxes and personal
property taxes account for the remaining 5 percent. Because most property taxes are local taxes,
income taxes account for the overwhelming portion of deductible state taxes.
Effect of the SALT Deduction on Federal Income Tax Progressivity
High-income households are more likely than low-or moderate-income households to benefit
directly from the state and local tax (SALT) deduction. The amount of state and local taxes paid,
the probability of itemizing deductions, and the reduction in federal income taxes for each dollar
of state and local taxes deducted all increase with income.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 15
Individuals who claim the SALT deduction decrease their federal tax liability by the
amount of their deductible state and local taxes multiplied by their federal marginal income tax
rate. For example, each additional $100 of state income tax for taxpayers in the 35 percent
federal tax bracket would increase their net combined federal and state tax by only $65 if they
claimed the SALT deduction on their federal return. Because both the likelihood of itemizing and
the marginal tax rate increase with income, a large share of the benefits from the deduction is
concentrated among taxpayers in the upper part of the income distribution.
Taxpayers who claim the SALT deduction may not be able to reduce their taxes if they pay
the individual AMT. The AMT is a parallel tax to the regular individual income tax, intended to
limit the use of certain deductions, exemptions, and exclusions by higher-income taxpayers,
although not all AMT taxpayers have particularly high income. Taxpayers potentially subject to
the AMT must calculate their taxes separately under the rules for the regular income tax and the
rules for the AMT and pay the higher of the two.
15
When calculating the AMT, taxpayers may not
claim personal exemptions and certain itemized deductions, the largest of which is the SALT
deduction. The disallowance of the SALT deduction is the reason why a majority of AMT
taxpayers are subject to the AMT.
In 2011, 76 percent of the reduction in federal income taxes from the SALT deduction
went to people in the top income quintile; 28 percent of the tax saving went to people in the top 1
percent (table 4). The deduction was worth 1.1 percent of after-tax income for the taxpayers in
top quintile on average and 1.6 percent for those in the top 1 percent. The tax saving was slightly
lower for taxpayers in the 95th to 99th percentile of the income distribution than for other
groups in the top quintile because a larger percentage of taxpayers in the 95th to 99th percentile
pay the AMT and thus lose the tax saving from the SALT deduction.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 16
Effect of the SALT Deduction on State Income Tax Progressivity
The SALT deduction encourages states to rely more heavily on deductible taxes, such as income
or sales taxes, than they would without the deduction. It can also encourage states to shift more
of the state income tax burden to higher-income taxpayers who are more likely to claim a federal
deduction for those taxes and who save more in federal income taxes for each dollar of state
income taxes claimed. This shifting of state income tax burdens is one of the ways low- and
moderate-income taxpayers benefit indirectly from the SALT deduction.
An important consideration is how much the SALT deduction actually affects state and
local tax policy. Several empirical studies have found a measurable effect of the SALT deduction
on the mix of state and local taxes, but only a few of them also have found an effect of the
deduction on either total state and local revenues or expenditures. For the most part, these
studies all consider the effect of the “tax price” of raising state and local revenuesthat is, what
fraction of the tax people actually pay.
The tax price of one dollar of state and local taxes is one dollar for most taxpayers in the
state or localitythey bear the full cost of the tax but the tax price for taxpayers who itemize
their federal deductions is less than one because each dollar paid in state and local taxes reduces
their federal income tax. For example, the net cost to a taxpayer in the 35 percent federal income
tax bracket who itemizes his or her tax deductions is $0.65 ($1.00 of state taxes minus $0.35 of
federal tax saving). The marginal tax price of deductible taxes across all taxpayers with the state
TABLE 4
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 17
or locality will thus depend on the proportion of taxpayers who itemize federal deductions and
their federal marginal tax rates.
States might be expected to shift more or less of their tax burden to high-income
taxpayers (or to make compensating changes to the distribution of spending) in response to
changes in the tax price. They can do this by making the income tax more or less progressive or
shifting to or from other taxes, such as the sales tax. Several studies found that the degree of
progressivity of state income taxes is sensitive to the tax price. Chernick (1992) looked at the
effect of the tax price on state income tax progressivity for a cross-section of states in 1985. He
found that a higher tax price, either because a state had fewer itemizers or because itemizers in
the state had lower federal tax rates, was consistent with a less progressive income tax structure.
Scott and Triest (1993) measured the progressivity of state taxes before and after
enactment of the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 and the Tax Reform Act of 1986. Among
many other changes, both acts reduced federal marginal income tax rates. This not only raised
the tax price of state income taxes but also increased their effective progressivity, where the
effective progressivity includes the value of the federal subsidy for the SALT deduction. If state
lawmakers take account of the SALT deduction in setting tax policy, the expected response to a
reduction in federal marginal tax rates and the resulting decrease in the federal subsidy might
include lowering state income tax rates for higher-income taxpayers which would reduce the
statutory progressivity of those taxes. Scott and Triest found evidence that this occurred but
that the changes were not large enough to fully offset the federal changes. Thus, the effective
progressivity of state income taxes increased following the federal reforms.
THE SALT DEDUCTION AND RECENT STATE INCOME TAX REFORMS
Increases in federal marginal tax rates raise the value of the SALT deduction and lower the
effective tax price of deductible state and local taxes for high-income taxpayers. They also
reduce the effective progressivity of state income taxes if the tax saving from the federal
deduction is subtracted from state income taxes. An interesting question is whether some states,
particularly those with many high-income taxpayers affected by recent federal income tax
increases, responded to the lower tax price and the effective reduction in state income tax
progressivity by raising their own top tax rates in response, driven by the ability to export these
tax increases.
Changes in Federal Income Taxes between 2011 and 2014
The American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 permanently extended many of the federal tax cuts
that were temporarily enacted in 2001 and 2003 but let the temporary rate cuts expire for
taxpayers with taxable income exceeding $400,000 ($450,000 for married couples). This
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 18
effectively raised the marginal tax rates on ordinary income from 35 percent to 39.6 percent and
the rate on dividends and capital gains from 15 percent to 20 percent for those taxpayers
starting in 2013. In addition, a 3.8 percent surtax on net investment income for taxpayers with
income exceeding $200,000 ($250,000 for married couples) enacted by Affordable Care Act
took effect in 2013. The surtax, which is not indexed for inflation, raised the top tax rate on some
investment income to 43.4 percent and the top rate on capital gains and dividends to 23.8
percent (not including the effect of provisions, such as the limit on itemized deductions, that
phase-out certain tax benefits for high-income taxpayers).
The increase in the top federal rates thus lowered the tax price of a dollar of state and
local taxes from 65 cents to 60.4 cents for high-income taxpayers who claimed a deduction for
those taxes (and who were not subject to AMT).
16
In effect, the federal government paid about
40 percent of any additional state taxes levied on high-income taxpayers.
Changes in State Income Taxes between 2011 and 2014
Very few states took advantage of the increase in the federal subsidy by raising their tax rates. In
fact, more states lowered their top tax rates than raised them. These actions occurred in part
because several states had temporarily raised marginal tax rates to help balance their budgets
following the Great Recession and they allowed those increases to expire as scheduled. These
changes also reflected changes in policies by state governments as many states proposed or
enacted reductions in individual and corporate income taxes while increasing sales taxes.
17
California was one of the few states that raised its top tax rate. In 2011, the highest
regular income tax rate of 9.3 percent in California applied to income over $48,000 ($96,000 for
couples). An additional 1 percent tax on income over $1 million brought the top rate to 10.3
percent. Following passage of a voter-approved referendum in December 2012 (Proposition
30),the regular income tax rate rose to 10.3 percent for income over $250,000 ($500,000 for
couples), 11.3 percent for income over $300,000 ($600,000 for couples), and 12.30 percent for
income over $500,000 ($1 million for couples). With the additional 1 percent tax on income over
$1 million still in place, the top tax rate became 13.3 percent.
Several other states also raised their top marginal income tax rates by lesser amounts.
Connecticut raised the top marginal income tax rate from 6.5 percent on income
exceeding $500,000 to 6.7 percent on income exceeding $250,000 starting January 1,
2012, and replaced its three-bracket system with a six-bracket system;
DC raised its marginal tax rate on income above $350,000 from 8.5 percent to 8.95
percent starting in 2012;
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 19
Maryland raised its top marginal tax rate from 5.5 percent to 5.75 percent for taxpayers
with income over $100,000 ($150,000 for married couples) starting in 2012; and
Minnesota introduced a new top tax bracket for joint filers with income over $250,000
and a tax rate of 9.85 percent in 2012.
In contrast, many more states reduced their tax rates after 2011, Kansas and North
Carolina enacted the most sweeping tax cuts. Kansas passed legislation in 2012 reducing the
number of tax brackets from three to two and cutting the top rate from 6.45 percent to 4.9
percent in 2013, and to 4.8 percent in 2014. It also repealed several income tax credits and
exempted non-wage business income of pass-through business (such as sole proprietorships,
partnerships, and S-corporations) from income tax. North Carolina replaced its graduated tax
rates of 6.0 percent, 7.0 percent, and a top rate of 7.75 percent with a single flat rate of 5.8
percent in 2014 and 5.75 percent thereafter. It also eliminated certain deductions, exemptions,
and tax credits, including the state EITC.
Other states also reduced income tax rates after 2011.
Delaware’s top rate dropped from 6.95 percent in 2011 to 6.6 percent in 2014, although it
had been scheduled to revert to its pre-2010 rate of 5.95 percent;
Idaho reduced its top rate from 7.8 percent to 7.4 percent;
Maine approved legislation in 2011 reducing the number of tax brackets from four to
three and the top income tax rate from 8.5 percent to 7.95 percent starting in 2013;
North Dakota reduced its top rate from 3.99 to 3.22 percent starting in 2013;
Ohio reduced tax rates by 9 percent, taking the top rate down from 5.925 percent to
5.392 percent;
Oregon reduced its two top tax rates from 10.8 percent and 11.0 percent in the top two
brackets to 9.9 percent in a single top bracket that combined the previous two; and
Oklahoma and Wisconsin also reduced their top tax rate between 2011 and 2014.
New York’s top tax rate in 2012 was lower than the rate in 2011, but it was higher than
the rate that was scheduled to take effect when temporary tax increases enacted in 2009
expired. New York introduced two additional tax brackets for higher-income taxpayers in 2009.
This so-called “millionaire’s tax” added a tax rate of 7.85 percent for taxpayers with income over
$200,000 ($300,000 for married couples) and a rate of 8.97 percent for all taxpayers with
income over $500,000. Before introducing those rates, New York’s top tax rate was 6.85
percent.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 20
Rather than simply letting the millionaire’s tax expire at the end of 2011, New York
enacted a new rate schedule starting in 2012. The new tax rates ranged from 6.45 percent to
6.85 percent for income between $20,000 ($40,000 for couples) and $1 million ($2 million for
couples), and a rate of 8.82 percent on income over $1 million ($2 million for couples).
Some single-rate states also lowered their rate.
Massachusetts lowered its rate from 5.25 percent to 5.15 percent, continuing a phased-in
reduction that began in 2002; and
Michigan lowered its tax rate from 4.35 percent to 4.25 percent.
Changes in Federal and State Income Tax Progressivity between 2011 and 2014
Federal individual income taxes became more progressive between 2011 and 2014, but state
income taxes did not. In 2011, the average federal individual income tax rate ranged from -4.8
percent for households in the lowest income quintile to 13.1 percent in the highest income
quintile; under the tax law in 2014 they ranged from -4.9 percent to 14.4 percent (table 5). The
average tax rate for the top 1 percent went from 20.2 percent to 24.0 percent. In contrast,
average state individual income tax rates hardly changed. In 2011 they ranged from zero for
those in the lowest income quintile to 3.0 percent for the highest income quintile and were the
same under 2014 tax law for all but the two highest income groups.
The summary measures of tax progressivity show an increase in the RS index at the
federal level between 2011 and 2014 (table 6). Holding income constant at its 2011 level and
distribution but applying 2014 tax law deflated to 2011 incomes increases the RS index for
TABLE 5
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 21
federal income taxes: taxes under 2014 law had a slightly greater equalizing effect on after-tax
income than taxes under 2011 law. The K index for federal income taxes was virtually
unchanged. There was no change in the overall progressivity of state income taxes: both the RS
index and the K index for state income taxes under 2014 law were unchanged from their 2011
values. Combined federal and state income taxes showed a small increase in progressivity for the
RS index, but no change for the K index.
Income tax progressivity did change in some individual states, although none of those
changes were comparable in magnitude to the change for federal income taxes. The RS index
increased between 2011 and 2014 in Minnesota, California, and Illinois, as the income tax
systems in those states became more redistributive; the index decreased in the most in Kansas,
North Carolina, New York, and Michigan, indicating the opposite effect (figure 4). As noted,
California and Minnesota increased their top income tax rates, while Illinois doubled its EITC.
Kansas and North Carolina enacted significant income tax cuts, including a substantial reduction
in the top tax rates, New York reduced its top marginal tax rate, and Michigan both reduced its
top rate and cut the state EITC from 20 percent to 6 percent of the federal credit. The K index
was virtually unchanged in most states between 2011 and 2014.
TABLE 6
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 22
CONCLUSION
Federal income taxes are more progressive than state income taxes overall. State income tax
systems vary greatly in progressivity. Changes in federal tax law between 2011 and 2014
increased the progressivity of federal income taxes and reduced the effective progressivity of
state income taxes by increasing the tax savings from the SALT deduction. States could have
responded and restored the effective progressivity by raising top marginal rates, but few did.
More states reduced their top rate rather than increasing it. On net, however, state income taxes
were about as progressive under 2014 rules as they were in 2011.
APPENDIX
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 23
The primary data source for the Tax Policy Center (TPC) federal and state income tax models is
the 2006 public-use file produced by the Statistics of Income division of the Internal Revenue
Service. The public-use file contains 145,858 records with detailed, anonymous information from
federal individual income tax returns filed in the 2006 calendar year. Starting with the 2006 data,
TPC uses published tabulations of tax data from 2011 to create a representative tax file for that
year. TPC then adds additional information on demographic characteristics and sources of
income not reported on tax returns through a constrained match of the tax file with data for
2011 from the March 2012 Current Population Survey of the US Census Bureau. The match also
generates a sample of individuals who do not file tax returns. The final data file contains filers and
nonfilers and provides a representative sample of the entire population.
To impute state weights to the database, TPC uses a constrained, parametric regression
methodology proposed by Schirm and Zaslavsky (1997). The data file with the state weights is
then run through detailed tax calculators that compute federal and state individual income tax
liability for all filers in the sample. For more information on the weighting methodology see
Khitatrakun, Mermin, and Francis (2015).
We calculated federal income taxes using the TPC tax model,
18
income taxes for the 43
states with an income tax and DC using the TPC version of state income tax calculators originally
developed by John Bakija,
19
and Gini coefficients, the Reynolds-Smolensky index, and Kakwani
index using the sgini routine developed for STATA by Phillippe Van Kerm.
20
We use a broad measure of before-tax income, called “expanded cash income” or ECI, to
rank tax units by income and to calculate average tax rates. ECI is measured as adjusted gross
income (AGI) plus: above-the-line adjustments (e.g., IRA deductions, student loan interest, self-
employed health insurance deduction, etc.), employer-paid health insurance and other
nontaxable fringe benefits, employee and employer contributions to tax-deferred retirement
savings plans, tax-exempt interest, nontaxable Social Security benefits, nontaxable pension and
retirement income, accruals within defined benefit pension plans, inside buildup within defined
contribution retirement accounts, cash and cash-like (such as SNAP benefits) transfer income,
the employer’s share of payroll taxes, and imputed corporate income tax liability.
21
NOTES
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 24
1
Each quintile represents 20 percent of the US population, including people who do not file federal income tax returns,
ranked by income.
2
The Congressional Budget Office (2013, 2014) analyzes the progressivity of federal individual and corporate income,
payroll, and excise taxes. ITEP (2015) and Cooper, Lutz, and Palumbo (2015) analyze the progressivity of combined federal
and state taxes.
3
Although the tax saving from each dollar of an exemption or a deduction is higher for higher-income taxpayers (because
their marginal tax rate is higher), the saving as a percentage of income is higher for lower-income taxpayers.
4
The lower rates on dividend and capital gains reflect in part that income derived from corporations is taxed once at the
entity level by the corporate income tax and again at the personal level by the individual income tax. A complete
assessment of the effect on progressivity of the income tax treatment of capital gains and dividends would also account for
the effects of the corporate income tax.
5
Ranked in order, the sources of state general revenue in 2013 were: intergovernmental transfers (31 percent), sales taxes
(19 percent), charges and miscellaneous fees (19 percent), individual income taxes (18 percent), and other taxes (9
percent). “Tax Policy Center Briefing Book: What are the sources of revenue for state governments?” Urban-Brookings Tax
Policy Center, Washington D.C. Accessed May 20, 2016.
6
Local jurisdictions in 14 states levy their own income taxes. We do not include local income taxes in this analysis.
7
Households in states that do not have an individual income tax are included in the distribution.
8
State and Local Finance Data Query System,” Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, Washington D.C. Accessed March 29,
2016.
9
The Gini coefficient is a widely used measure of income in equality. See Congressional Budget Office (2013), pp. 8-9 and
pp. 39-42 for a discussion of calculating and interpreting the Gini coefficient.
10
See Kakwani (1977) and Reynolds and Smolensky (1977).
11
The RS index and the K index are related. It is possible to derive the RS index from the K index by adjusting for the
average tax rate and the reranking of households when ranking by before- and after-tax income. See Creedy (1999).
12
See Mason (2013).
13
See Sammartino and Rueben (2016) for a discussion of the federal tax deduction and various options for reform.
14
The American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 partially reinstated the sales tax deduction, which the Tax Reform Act of 1986
had eliminated. Before the Tax Reform Act of 1986, taxpayers could deduct both income taxes and general sales taxes. The
2004 law allowed taxpayers to deduct either income taxes or sales taxes but not both. Subsequent legislation extended that
provision through 2014 and made it permanent in 2015.
15
Technically, the AMT is the difference between a taxpayer’s regular income tax liability and tax liability calculated
according to the rules for the AMT. If the difference is greater than zero, the taxpayer must pay the AMT in addition to his
or her regular income tax.
16
The tax price can be slightly lower than 60.4 percent in some cases because a portion of state and local taxes are
deductible from investment income subject to the 3.8 percent net investment income tax.
17
See NCSL 2011, 2012, and 2013 for details about the state income tax changes enacted over this period.
18
See Brief Description of the Tax Model,” Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, Washington DC. Accessed March 29, 2016.
19
See Documentation for a Comprehensive Historical U.S. Federal and State Income Tax Calculator Program,” Jon Bakija,
Department of Economics, Williams College, Williamstown, MA. Accessed April 20, 2016.
20
See Generalized Gini and Concentration coefficients (with factor decomposition) in Stata,” Philippe Van Kerm
CEPS/INSTEAD, Luxembourg. Accessed April 20, 2016.
21
See “Income Measure Used in Distributional Analyses by the Tax Policy Center,Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center,
Washington DC. Accessed June 16, 2016.
REFERENCES
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 25
Chernick, Howard. 1992. “A Model of the Distributional Incidence of State and Local Taxes.” Public
Finance Review 20 (4): 57285.
Congressional Budget Office. 2013. Trends in the Distribution of Household Income between 1979 and
2007. Washington DC: Congressional Budget Office.
———. 2014. The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2011. Washington DC:
Congressional Budget Office.
Cooper, Daniel H., Byron F. Lutz, and Michael G. Palumbo. 2015. “The Role of Taxes in Mitigating
Income Inequality across the U. S. States.” National Tax Journal 68: 94374.
Creedy, John. 1999. “Taxation, Redistribution and Progressivity: An Introduction.” Australian Economic
Review 32 (4): 41022.
ITEP (Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy). 2015. “Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax
Systems in All 50 States.” Washington DC: Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy.
Kakwani, Nanak C. 1977. “Measurement of Tax Progressivity: An International Comparison.” Economic
Journal 87 (345): 7180.
Khitatrakun, Surachai, Gordon B. T. Mermin, and Norton Francis. 2015. “Incorporating State Analysis
into the Tax Policy Center’s Microsimulation Model: Documentation and Methodology.” Washington
DC: Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center.
Mason, Ruth. 2013. “Delegating Up: State Conformity with the Federal Tax Base.” Duke Law Journal 62
(7): 12671348.
NCSL (National Conference of State Legislators). 2011. “State Tax Actions 2011.” Washington DC:
National Conference of State Legislators.
———. 2012. “State Tax Actions 2012.” Washington DC: National Conference of State Legislators.
———. 2013. “State Tax Actions 2013.” Washington DC: National Conference of State Legislators.
Reynolds, Morgan, and Eugene Smolensky. 1977. Public Expenditures, Taxes and the Distribution of
Income: The United States 1950, 1961, 1970. New York: Academic Press.
Sammartino, Frank, and Kim Rueben. 2016. “Reforming the State and Local Tax Deduction.”
Washington DC: Tax Policy Center.
TAX POLICY CENTER | URBAN INSTITUTE & BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 26
Schirm, Allen L., and Alan M. Zaslavsky. 1997. “Reweighting Households to Develop Microsimulation
Estimates for State.” Proceedings of the Section on Survey Research Methods. Alexandria VA: American
Statistical Association.
Scott, Charles E., and Robert K. Triest. 1993. “The Relationship between Federal and State Individual
Income Tax Progressivity.” National Tax Journal 46 (2): 95108.
Copyright © 2016. Urban Institute. Permission is granted for reproduction of this file, with attribution to the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center.
The Tax Policy Center is a joint venture of the
Urban Institute and Brookings Institution.
For more information, visit taxpolicycenter.org
or email info@taxpolicycenter.org